• Undergraduate
  • High School
  • Architecture
  • American History
  • Asian History
  • Antique Literature
  • American Literature
  • Asian Literature
  • Classic English Literature
  • World Literature
  • Creative Writing
  • Linguistics
  • Criminal Justice
  • Legal Issues
  • Anthropology
  • Archaeology
  • Political Science
  • World Affairs
  • African-American Studies
  • East European Studies
  • Latin-American Studies
  • Native-American Studies
  • West European Studies
  • Family and Consumer Science
  • Social Issues
  • Women and Gender Studies
  • Social Work
  • Natural Sciences
  • Pharmacology
  • Earth science
  • Agriculture
  • Agricultural Studies
  • Computer Science
  • IT Management
  • Mathematics
  • Investments
  • Engineering and Technology
  • Engineering
  • Aeronautics
  • Medicine and Health
  • Alternative Medicine
  • Communications and Media
  • Advertising
  • Communication Strategies
  • Public Relations
  • Educational Theories
  • Teacher's Career
  • Chicago/Turabian
  • Company Analysis
  • Education Theories
  • Shakespeare
  • Canadian Studies
  • Food Safety
  • Relation of Global Warming and Extreme Weather Condition
  • Movie Review
  • Admission Essay
  • Annotated Bibliography
  • Application Essay
  • Article Critique
  • Article Review
  • Article Writing
  • Book Review
  • Business Plan
  • Business Proposal
  • Capstone Project
  • Cover Letter
  • Creative Essay
  • Dissertation
  • Dissertation - Abstract
  • Dissertation - Conclusion
  • Dissertation - Discussion
  • Dissertation - Hypothesis
  • Dissertation - Introduction
  • Dissertation - Literature
  • Dissertation - Methodology
  • Dissertation - Results
  • GCSE Coursework
  • Grant Proposal
  • Marketing Plan
  • Multiple Choice Quiz
  • Personal Statement
  • Power Point Presentation
  • Power Point Presentation With Speaker Notes
  • Questionnaire
  • Reaction Paper
  • Research Paper
  • Research Proposal
  • SWOT analysis
  • Thesis Paper
  • Online Quiz
  • Literature Review
  • Movie Analysis
  • Statistics problem
  • Math Problem
  • All papers examples
  • How It Works
  • Money Back Policy
  • Terms of Use
  • Privacy Policy
  • We Are Hiring

Fiscal Policy, Essay Example

Pages: 4

Words: 1082

Hire a Writer for Custom Essay

Use 10% Off Discount: "custom10" in 1 Click 👇

You are free to use it as an inspiration or a source for your own work.

Fiscal policy is basically noted as the procedural policies that are imposed by the government to make sure that the national budget is used for the needs and demands of the public. It also constitutes how the government is able to gain revenue from its national and public operations thus making a distinct effect on increasing national budget for the overall development of the country. The consistency on how the different policies of the government are followed especially when it comes to monetary budget specifically affects the overall development of the nation. This is the reason why the status of a nation’s fiscal policy is considered highly important especially when it comes to building the nation and the lives of its people.

In the article of Richard and Peggy Musgrave, a distinct identification on the different roles that the fiscal policy take in relation to the overall development and establishment of a nation’s community, it could be noted that in the article, the authors pointed out how fiscal policy could affect the overall condition of the public’s living status. The authors specifically indicated that there are particular functions that the fiscal policy responds to. Among these functions, the capacity of the government to allocate funds and resources to different households that it is supposed to serve is seemingly considered as the most important aspect of its application. The function of a fiscal policy to create a pattern of procedures that will specifically help the members of the society to realize their financial capacities creates a distinct element of balance among the people, likely aiming to develop a more dependable economy that specifically satisfies the majority of the people operating within it. Question is, what particular characteristics does a fiscal policy need to contend with to be noted as efficient enough in making a distinct impact upon the development of the country and its people? At present, most nations tend to operate under the capacity of earning revenue from the public and making sure that such revenue is redistributed to the people in a balanced manner. This is often noted as the stabilization function of fiscal policies. However, a huge conflict between revenues and redistribution of resources is found to have a distinct effect on how efficient a particular policy is notably able to provide what the public requires for personal satisfaction and for the establishment of government trust. The conflict specifically entails to define the collection of revenue through tax application on social goods to be quite inadequately redistributed to the people. This is because of the fact that tax price tagged on particular products and services sold to the public follow a distinct price-range that is applied to everyone regardless of their income, their employment and other elements that are necessarily able to define whether or not a person is able to respond to a particular price-offer in the market. Most of these products are basic which includes food, shelter, clothing and education. The tax placed atop the original price of the said products and services are fully passed on to consumers in the public. People who have a lower range of income compared to others may have a difficulty in acquiring the services and products offered to them both by the private and public entities in the market. This is most often than not the result of meager earnings that they get from their jobs. Most often than not, the government responds to this through creating public projects that are designed to generally give ease to the lives of the people. However, if individuals living within the lower edge of the economy could not enjoy the benefit from such public projects, how then could such pattern of redistribution of resources be called ‘balanced’ or ‘equal’ in nature?

Taking from the details of the written statements of both Peggy and Richard Musgrave, one specific truth could be derived, that when it comes to economy, the overall concept of balance and equality cannot be fully realized especially when the government is going to depend on the traditional way of managing funds as relatively connected to the considerable operations of capitalism. Private and public sectors operating in the market all have one purpose in relation to their existence and that is to gain the amount of revenue they hope to get from the people. Regardless of the economic capacities of the people in the society, they are supposed to respond to the pattern of paying to the government what the government is supposedly ‘due’. While it is said that such operation is specifically vital to the creation of a balanced economy, it does not benefit all members of the community as expected. The truth behind the establishment of a good economy may seemingly not provide good news to all the members of the society in an overall context. While this is true, it could not be denied that this is the same system that constitutes the creation of an operation that pushes every individual in the household sectors to find a way to reach a higher level of economic competence which again boosts the overall status of the national economy. True, in the end, however a fiscal policy is established or created around the needs of the public, the realization of its benefits specifically depend on how the households are to take into account their role in contributing to the system through making their own moves in reaching a higher level of the economic ladder. It is only through this manner that each household is to get the chance to benefit from their hard earned money through the returned values of the tax that they pay for whenever they consume basic products and basic services that are offered by both public and private entities in the market. The truth is, this particular imbalance among individuals in a specific nation is considered effective in developing and keeping a healthy national economy among many countries around the globe today. Relatively, such system has been seen to have effectively fueled development among different regions of the world; although it is a sad truth in relation to the condition on how fiscal policies are applied, it is considered as vital section that brings about a distinct realization of results which better indicates a distinction on how people tend to contribute to the development of their community within an overall context.

Peretz, P. (1987). The Politics of American Economic Policy. Section Article: Musgrave, R and Musgrave, P. Fiscal Function: An Overview.

Stuck with your Essay?

Get in touch with one of our experts for instant help!

Strategic Competitiveness, Essay Example

Ocular Ischemic Syndrome, Case Study Example

Time is precious

don’t waste it!

Plagiarism-free guarantee

Privacy guarantee

Secure checkout

Money back guarantee

E-book

Related Essay Samples & Examples

Voting as a civic responsibility, essay example.

Pages: 1

Words: 287

Utilitarianism and Its Applications, Essay Example

Words: 356

The Age-Related Changes of the Older Person, Essay Example

Pages: 2

Words: 448

The Problems ESOL Teachers Face, Essay Example

Pages: 8

Words: 2293

Should English Be the Primary Language? Essay Example

Words: 999

The Term “Social Construction of Reality”, Essay Example

Words: 371

Economics Help

Fiscal Policy

Definition of fiscal policy

Fiscal policy involves the government changing the levels of taxation and government spending in order to influence aggregate demand (AD) and the level of economic activity.

  • AD is the total level of planned expenditure in an economy (AD = C+ I + G + X – M)

The purpose of Fiscal Policy

  • Stimulate economic growth in a period of a recession.
  • Keep inflation low (the UK government has a target of 2%)
  • Fiscal policy aims to stabilise economic growth, avoiding a boom and bust economic cycle.

Fiscal policy is often used in conjunction with monetary policy. In fact, governments often prefer monetary policy for stabilising the economy.

Expansionary (or loose) fiscal policy

  • This involves increasing AD.
  • Therefore the government will increase spending (G) and cut taxes (T). Lower taxes will increase consumers spending because they have more disposable income (C)
  • This will tend to worsen the government budget deficit, and the government will need to increase borrowing.

Diagram showing effect of expansionary fiscal policy

ad-increase

Deflationary (or tight) fiscal policy

  • This involves decreasing AD.
  • Therefore the government will cut government spending (G) and/or increase taxes. Higher taxes will reduce consumer spending (C)
  • Tight fiscal policy will tend to cause an improvement in the government budget deficit.

Diagram showing the effect of tight fiscal policy

fall-in-ad-arrow-ad-as

UK fiscal policy

budget-deficit-uk-percent-gdp

UK Budget deficit

In 2009, the government pursued expansionary fiscal policy. In response to a deep recession (GDP fell 6%) the government cut VAT in a bid to boost consumer spending. This caused a big rise in government borrowing (2009-10). (Government borrowing also rose because of the recession leading to lower tax revenue)

When the new coalition government came into power in May 2010, they argued the deficit was too high and then announced plans to reduce government borrowing. This involved spending limits. These austerity measures were a factor in causing lower economic growth in 2011 and 2012.

Fine tuning – fiscal policy

  • Definition of Fine Tuning : This involves maintaining a steady rate of economic growth by using fiscal policy. For example, if growth is below the trend rate of growth, the government can cut tax to boost spending and economic growth. If growth is too fast and inflationary, the government can increase income tax to slow down consumer spending and reduce economic growth.
  • In theory, the government can make incremental changes to spending and taxation levels to slow down or speed up the economy.

Difficulties of fine tuning

In the real world, fine tuning is difficult to achieve due to several factors.

  • Time lags. It takes several months for government spending to feed its way into the economy. By the time government spending increases it may be too late.
  • Political costs. Raising taxes to reduce inflation will impose political costs as people will not like the idea of higher taxes. Before an election it would be hard for government to raise taxes – merely to fine tune economic growth rate.
  • Difficulty of forecasting. Fine tuning requires good information about  current  state of economy and likely forecasts  of growth. Governments may struggle to know the extent of the output gap.

Terms relating to fiscal policy

  • Fiscal Stance : This refers to whether the government is increasing AD or decreasing AD, e.g. expansionary or tight fiscal policy
  • Automatic fiscal stabilisers – If the economy is growing, people will automatically pay more taxes ( VAT and Income tax) and the Government will spend less on unemployment benefits. The increased T and lower G will act as a check on AD. But, in a recession, the opposite will occur with tax revenue falling but increased government spending on benefits, this will help increase AD
  • Discretionary fiscal stabilisers – This is a deliberate attempt by the government to affect AD and stabilise the economy, e.g. in a boom the government will increase taxes to reduce inflation.
  • Primary budget deficit – a measure of government spending – tax receipts but ignoring interest payments on the debt.
  • The multiplier effect . When an increase in injections causes a bigger final increase in Real GDP.
  • Injections (J) – This is an increase of expenditure in the circular flow, it includes govt spending(G), Exports (X) and Investment (I)
  • Withdrawals (W) – This is leakages from the circular flow This is household income that is not spent on the circular flow. It includes: Net savings (S) + Net Taxes (T) + Net Imports (M)

Criticism of fiscal policy

  • The government may have poor information about the state of the economy and struggle to have the best information about what the economy needs.
  • Time lags. To increase government spending will take time. It could take several months for a government decision to filter through into the economy and actually affect AD. By then it may be too late.
  • Crowding out. Some economists argue that expansionary fiscal policy (higher government spending) will not increase AD because the higher government spending will crowd out the private sector. This is because the government have to borrow from the private sector who will then have lower funds for private investment.
  • Government spending is inefficient. Free market economists argue that higher government spending will tend to be wasted on inefficient spending projects. Also, it can then be difficult to reduce spending in the future because interest groups put political pressure on maintaining stimulus spending as permanent.
  • Higher borrowing costs. Under certain conditions, expansionary fiscal policy can lead to higher bond yields, increasing the cost of debt repayments.
  • Criticisms of Fiscal Policy – More detail on criticisms of fiscal policy

Evaluation of fiscal policy

The success of fiscal policy will depend on several factors, such as

  • It depends on the size of the multiplier. If the multiplier effect is large, then changes in government spending will have a bigger effect on overall demand.
  • It depends on the state of the economy. Fiscal policy is most effective in a deep recession where monetary policy is insufficient to boost demand. In a deep recession (liquidity trap). Higher government spending will not cause crowding out because the private sector saving has increased substantially. See: Liquidity trap and fiscal policy – why fiscal policy is more important during a liquidity trap.
  • It depends on other factors in the economy. For example, if the government pursue expansionary fiscal policy, but interest rates rise, and the global economy is in a recession, it may be insufficient to boost demand.
  • Bond yields. If there is concern over the state of government finances, the government may not be able to borrow to finance fiscal policy. Countries in the Eurozone experienced this problem in the 2008-13 recession.

Brief history of fiscal policy

  • Keynes advocated the use of fiscal policy as a way to stimulate economies during the great depression.
  • Fiscal Policy was particularly used in the 50s and 60s to stabilise economic cycles. These policies were broadly referred to as ‘Keynesian’
  • In the 1970s and 80s governments tended to prefer monetary policy for influencing the economy. Fiscal policy became more prominent during the great depression of 2008-13

US fiscal policy

us-tight-fiscal-policy

Evaluation of US expansionary fiscal policy in 2009

Further Reading on Fiscal Policy

  • Deflationary Fiscal Policy – impact on the economy of raising taxes and cutting spending.
  • The difference between monetary and fiscal policy – Monetary policy has a similar aim to fiscal policy but involves changing interest rates and other monetary policies.
  • Does fiscal policy solve unemployment?

Essays on fiscal policy

  • Discuss the difficulties of recovering from recessions
  • Is austerity self-defeating?

Last updated: 10th July 2017, Tejvan Pettinger, www.economicshelp.org

web analytics

  • Search Menu

Sign in through your institution

  • Browse content in Arts and Humanities
  • Browse content in Archaeology
  • Anglo-Saxon and Medieval Archaeology
  • Archaeological Methodology and Techniques
  • Archaeology by Region
  • Archaeology of Religion
  • Archaeology of Trade and Exchange
  • Biblical Archaeology
  • Contemporary and Public Archaeology
  • Environmental Archaeology
  • Historical Archaeology
  • History and Theory of Archaeology
  • Industrial Archaeology
  • Landscape Archaeology
  • Mortuary Archaeology
  • Prehistoric Archaeology
  • Underwater Archaeology
  • Zooarchaeology
  • Browse content in Architecture
  • Architectural Structure and Design
  • History of Architecture
  • Residential and Domestic Buildings
  • Theory of Architecture
  • Browse content in Art
  • Art Subjects and Themes
  • History of Art
  • Industrial and Commercial Art
  • Theory of Art
  • Biographical Studies
  • Byzantine Studies
  • Browse content in Classical Studies
  • Classical History
  • Classical Philosophy
  • Classical Mythology
  • Classical Numismatics
  • Classical Literature
  • Classical Reception
  • Classical Art and Architecture
  • Classical Oratory and Rhetoric
  • Greek and Roman Epigraphy
  • Greek and Roman Law
  • Greek and Roman Papyrology
  • Greek and Roman Archaeology
  • Late Antiquity
  • Religion in the Ancient World
  • Social History
  • Digital Humanities
  • Browse content in History
  • Colonialism and Imperialism
  • Diplomatic History
  • Environmental History
  • Genealogy, Heraldry, Names, and Honours
  • Genocide and Ethnic Cleansing
  • Historical Geography
  • History by Period
  • History of Emotions
  • History of Agriculture
  • History of Education
  • History of Gender and Sexuality
  • Industrial History
  • Intellectual History
  • International History
  • Labour History
  • Legal and Constitutional History
  • Local and Family History
  • Maritime History
  • Military History
  • National Liberation and Post-Colonialism
  • Oral History
  • Political History
  • Public History
  • Regional and National History
  • Revolutions and Rebellions
  • Slavery and Abolition of Slavery
  • Social and Cultural History
  • Theory, Methods, and Historiography
  • Urban History
  • World History
  • Browse content in Language Teaching and Learning
  • Language Learning (Specific Skills)
  • Language Teaching Theory and Methods
  • Browse content in Linguistics
  • Applied Linguistics
  • Cognitive Linguistics
  • Computational Linguistics
  • Forensic Linguistics
  • Grammar, Syntax and Morphology
  • Historical and Diachronic Linguistics
  • History of English
  • Language Acquisition
  • Language Evolution
  • Language Reference
  • Language Variation
  • Language Families
  • Lexicography
  • Linguistic Anthropology
  • Linguistic Theories
  • Linguistic Typology
  • Phonetics and Phonology
  • Psycholinguistics
  • Sociolinguistics
  • Translation and Interpretation
  • Writing Systems
  • Browse content in Literature
  • Bibliography
  • Children's Literature Studies
  • Literary Studies (Asian)
  • Literary Studies (European)
  • Literary Studies (Eco-criticism)
  • Literary Studies (American)
  • Literary Studies (Romanticism)
  • Literary Studies (Modernism)
  • Literary Studies - World
  • Literary Studies (1500 to 1800)
  • Literary Studies (19th Century)
  • Literary Studies (20th Century onwards)
  • Literary Studies (African American Literature)
  • Literary Studies (British and Irish)
  • Literary Studies (Early and Medieval)
  • Literary Studies (Fiction, Novelists, and Prose Writers)
  • Literary Studies (Gender Studies)
  • Literary Studies (Graphic Novels)
  • Literary Studies (History of the Book)
  • Literary Studies (Plays and Playwrights)
  • Literary Studies (Poetry and Poets)
  • Literary Studies (Postcolonial Literature)
  • Literary Studies (Queer Studies)
  • Literary Studies (Science Fiction)
  • Literary Studies (Travel Literature)
  • Literary Studies (War Literature)
  • Literary Studies (Women's Writing)
  • Literary Theory and Cultural Studies
  • Mythology and Folklore
  • Shakespeare Studies and Criticism
  • Browse content in Media Studies
  • Browse content in Music
  • Applied Music
  • Dance and Music
  • Ethics in Music
  • Ethnomusicology
  • Gender and Sexuality in Music
  • Medicine and Music
  • Music Cultures
  • Music and Religion
  • Music and Media
  • Music and Culture
  • Music Education and Pedagogy
  • Music Theory and Analysis
  • Musical Scores, Lyrics, and Libretti
  • Musical Structures, Styles, and Techniques
  • Musicology and Music History
  • Performance Practice and Studies
  • Race and Ethnicity in Music
  • Sound Studies
  • Browse content in Performing Arts
  • Browse content in Philosophy
  • Aesthetics and Philosophy of Art
  • Epistemology
  • Feminist Philosophy
  • History of Western Philosophy
  • Metaphysics
  • Moral Philosophy
  • Non-Western Philosophy
  • Philosophy of Science
  • Philosophy of Language
  • Philosophy of Mind
  • Philosophy of Perception
  • Philosophy of Action
  • Philosophy of Law
  • Philosophy of Religion
  • Philosophy of Mathematics and Logic
  • Practical Ethics
  • Social and Political Philosophy
  • Browse content in Religion
  • Biblical Studies
  • Christianity
  • East Asian Religions
  • History of Religion
  • Judaism and Jewish Studies
  • Qumran Studies
  • Religion and Education
  • Religion and Health
  • Religion and Politics
  • Religion and Science
  • Religion and Law
  • Religion and Art, Literature, and Music
  • Religious Studies
  • Browse content in Society and Culture
  • Cookery, Food, and Drink
  • Cultural Studies
  • Customs and Traditions
  • Ethical Issues and Debates
  • Hobbies, Games, Arts and Crafts
  • Natural world, Country Life, and Pets
  • Popular Beliefs and Controversial Knowledge
  • Sports and Outdoor Recreation
  • Technology and Society
  • Travel and Holiday
  • Visual Culture
  • Browse content in Law
  • Arbitration
  • Browse content in Company and Commercial Law
  • Commercial Law
  • Company Law
  • Browse content in Comparative Law
  • Systems of Law
  • Competition Law
  • Browse content in Constitutional and Administrative Law
  • Government Powers
  • Judicial Review
  • Local Government Law
  • Military and Defence Law
  • Parliamentary and Legislative Practice
  • Construction Law
  • Contract Law
  • Browse content in Criminal Law
  • Criminal Procedure
  • Criminal Evidence Law
  • Sentencing and Punishment
  • Employment and Labour Law
  • Environment and Energy Law
  • Browse content in Financial Law
  • Banking Law
  • Insolvency Law
  • History of Law
  • Human Rights and Immigration
  • Intellectual Property Law
  • Browse content in International Law
  • Private International Law and Conflict of Laws
  • Public International Law
  • IT and Communications Law
  • Jurisprudence and Philosophy of Law
  • Law and Politics
  • Law and Society
  • Browse content in Legal System and Practice
  • Courts and Procedure
  • Legal Skills and Practice
  • Legal System - Costs and Funding
  • Primary Sources of Law
  • Regulation of Legal Profession
  • Medical and Healthcare Law
  • Browse content in Policing
  • Criminal Investigation and Detection
  • Police and Security Services
  • Police Procedure and Law
  • Police Regional Planning
  • Browse content in Property Law
  • Personal Property Law
  • Restitution
  • Study and Revision
  • Terrorism and National Security Law
  • Browse content in Trusts Law
  • Wills and Probate or Succession
  • Browse content in Medicine and Health
  • Browse content in Allied Health Professions
  • Arts Therapies
  • Clinical Science
  • Dietetics and Nutrition
  • Occupational Therapy
  • Operating Department Practice
  • Physiotherapy
  • Radiography
  • Speech and Language Therapy
  • Browse content in Anaesthetics
  • General Anaesthesia
  • Browse content in Clinical Medicine
  • Acute Medicine
  • Cardiovascular Medicine
  • Clinical Genetics
  • Clinical Pharmacology and Therapeutics
  • Dermatology
  • Endocrinology and Diabetes
  • Gastroenterology
  • Genito-urinary Medicine
  • Geriatric Medicine
  • Infectious Diseases
  • Medical Toxicology
  • Medical Oncology
  • Pain Medicine
  • Palliative Medicine
  • Rehabilitation Medicine
  • Respiratory Medicine and Pulmonology
  • Rheumatology
  • Sleep Medicine
  • Sports and Exercise Medicine
  • Clinical Neuroscience
  • Community Medical Services
  • Critical Care
  • Emergency Medicine
  • Forensic Medicine
  • Haematology
  • History of Medicine
  • Browse content in Medical Dentistry
  • Oral and Maxillofacial Surgery
  • Paediatric Dentistry
  • Restorative Dentistry and Orthodontics
  • Surgical Dentistry
  • Browse content in Medical Skills
  • Clinical Skills
  • Communication Skills
  • Nursing Skills
  • Surgical Skills
  • Medical Ethics
  • Medical Statistics and Methodology
  • Browse content in Neurology
  • Clinical Neurophysiology
  • Neuropathology
  • Nursing Studies
  • Browse content in Obstetrics and Gynaecology
  • Gynaecology
  • Occupational Medicine
  • Ophthalmology
  • Otolaryngology (ENT)
  • Browse content in Paediatrics
  • Neonatology
  • Browse content in Pathology
  • Chemical Pathology
  • Clinical Cytogenetics and Molecular Genetics
  • Histopathology
  • Medical Microbiology and Virology
  • Patient Education and Information
  • Browse content in Pharmacology
  • Psychopharmacology
  • Browse content in Popular Health
  • Caring for Others
  • Complementary and Alternative Medicine
  • Self-help and Personal Development
  • Browse content in Preclinical Medicine
  • Cell Biology
  • Molecular Biology and Genetics
  • Reproduction, Growth and Development
  • Primary Care
  • Professional Development in Medicine
  • Browse content in Psychiatry
  • Addiction Medicine
  • Child and Adolescent Psychiatry
  • Forensic Psychiatry
  • Learning Disabilities
  • Old Age Psychiatry
  • Psychotherapy
  • Browse content in Public Health and Epidemiology
  • Epidemiology
  • Public Health
  • Browse content in Radiology
  • Clinical Radiology
  • Interventional Radiology
  • Nuclear Medicine
  • Radiation Oncology
  • Reproductive Medicine
  • Browse content in Surgery
  • Cardiothoracic Surgery
  • Gastro-intestinal and Colorectal Surgery
  • General Surgery
  • Neurosurgery
  • Paediatric Surgery
  • Peri-operative Care
  • Plastic and Reconstructive Surgery
  • Surgical Oncology
  • Transplant Surgery
  • Trauma and Orthopaedic Surgery
  • Vascular Surgery
  • Browse content in Science and Mathematics
  • Browse content in Biological Sciences
  • Aquatic Biology
  • Biochemistry
  • Bioinformatics and Computational Biology
  • Developmental Biology
  • Ecology and Conservation
  • Evolutionary Biology
  • Genetics and Genomics
  • Microbiology
  • Molecular and Cell Biology
  • Natural History
  • Plant Sciences and Forestry
  • Research Methods in Life Sciences
  • Structural Biology
  • Systems Biology
  • Zoology and Animal Sciences
  • Browse content in Chemistry
  • Analytical Chemistry
  • Computational Chemistry
  • Crystallography
  • Environmental Chemistry
  • Industrial Chemistry
  • Inorganic Chemistry
  • Materials Chemistry
  • Medicinal Chemistry
  • Mineralogy and Gems
  • Organic Chemistry
  • Physical Chemistry
  • Polymer Chemistry
  • Study and Communication Skills in Chemistry
  • Theoretical Chemistry
  • Browse content in Computer Science
  • Artificial Intelligence
  • Computer Architecture and Logic Design
  • Game Studies
  • Human-Computer Interaction
  • Mathematical Theory of Computation
  • Programming Languages
  • Software Engineering
  • Systems Analysis and Design
  • Virtual Reality
  • Browse content in Computing
  • Business Applications
  • Computer Security
  • Computer Games
  • Computer Networking and Communications
  • Digital Lifestyle
  • Graphical and Digital Media Applications
  • Operating Systems
  • Browse content in Earth Sciences and Geography
  • Atmospheric Sciences
  • Environmental Geography
  • Geology and the Lithosphere
  • Maps and Map-making
  • Meteorology and Climatology
  • Oceanography and Hydrology
  • Palaeontology
  • Physical Geography and Topography
  • Regional Geography
  • Soil Science
  • Urban Geography
  • Browse content in Engineering and Technology
  • Agriculture and Farming
  • Biological Engineering
  • Civil Engineering, Surveying, and Building
  • Electronics and Communications Engineering
  • Energy Technology
  • Engineering (General)
  • Environmental Science, Engineering, and Technology
  • History of Engineering and Technology
  • Mechanical Engineering and Materials
  • Technology of Industrial Chemistry
  • Transport Technology and Trades
  • Browse content in Environmental Science
  • Applied Ecology (Environmental Science)
  • Conservation of the Environment (Environmental Science)
  • Environmental Sustainability
  • Environmentalist Thought and Ideology (Environmental Science)
  • Management of Land and Natural Resources (Environmental Science)
  • Natural Disasters (Environmental Science)
  • Nuclear Issues (Environmental Science)
  • Pollution and Threats to the Environment (Environmental Science)
  • Social Impact of Environmental Issues (Environmental Science)
  • History of Science and Technology
  • Browse content in Materials Science
  • Ceramics and Glasses
  • Composite Materials
  • Metals, Alloying, and Corrosion
  • Nanotechnology
  • Browse content in Mathematics
  • Applied Mathematics
  • Biomathematics and Statistics
  • History of Mathematics
  • Mathematical Education
  • Mathematical Finance
  • Mathematical Analysis
  • Numerical and Computational Mathematics
  • Probability and Statistics
  • Pure Mathematics
  • Browse content in Neuroscience
  • Cognition and Behavioural Neuroscience
  • Development of the Nervous System
  • Disorders of the Nervous System
  • History of Neuroscience
  • Invertebrate Neurobiology
  • Molecular and Cellular Systems
  • Neuroendocrinology and Autonomic Nervous System
  • Neuroscientific Techniques
  • Sensory and Motor Systems
  • Browse content in Physics
  • Astronomy and Astrophysics
  • Atomic, Molecular, and Optical Physics
  • Biological and Medical Physics
  • Classical Mechanics
  • Computational Physics
  • Condensed Matter Physics
  • Electromagnetism, Optics, and Acoustics
  • History of Physics
  • Mathematical and Statistical Physics
  • Measurement Science
  • Nuclear Physics
  • Particles and Fields
  • Plasma Physics
  • Quantum Physics
  • Relativity and Gravitation
  • Semiconductor and Mesoscopic Physics
  • Browse content in Psychology
  • Affective Sciences
  • Clinical Psychology
  • Cognitive Psychology
  • Cognitive Neuroscience
  • Criminal and Forensic Psychology
  • Developmental Psychology
  • Educational Psychology
  • Evolutionary Psychology
  • Health Psychology
  • History and Systems in Psychology
  • Music Psychology
  • Neuropsychology
  • Organizational Psychology
  • Psychological Assessment and Testing
  • Psychology of Human-Technology Interaction
  • Psychology Professional Development and Training
  • Research Methods in Psychology
  • Social Psychology
  • Browse content in Social Sciences
  • Browse content in Anthropology
  • Anthropology of Religion
  • Human Evolution
  • Medical Anthropology
  • Physical Anthropology
  • Regional Anthropology
  • Social and Cultural Anthropology
  • Theory and Practice of Anthropology
  • Browse content in Business and Management
  • Business Strategy
  • Business Ethics
  • Business History
  • Business and Government
  • Business and Technology
  • Business and the Environment
  • Comparative Management
  • Corporate Governance
  • Corporate Social Responsibility
  • Entrepreneurship
  • Health Management
  • Human Resource Management
  • Industrial and Employment Relations
  • Industry Studies
  • Information and Communication Technologies
  • International Business
  • Knowledge Management
  • Management and Management Techniques
  • Operations Management
  • Organizational Theory and Behaviour
  • Pensions and Pension Management
  • Public and Nonprofit Management
  • Social Issues in Business and Management
  • Strategic Management
  • Supply Chain Management
  • Browse content in Criminology and Criminal Justice
  • Criminal Justice
  • Criminology
  • Forms of Crime
  • International and Comparative Criminology
  • Youth Violence and Juvenile Justice
  • Development Studies
  • Browse content in Economics
  • Agricultural, Environmental, and Natural Resource Economics
  • Asian Economics
  • Behavioural Finance
  • Behavioural Economics and Neuroeconomics
  • Econometrics and Mathematical Economics
  • Economic Systems
  • Economic History
  • Economic Methodology
  • Economic Development and Growth
  • Financial Markets
  • Financial Institutions and Services
  • General Economics and Teaching
  • Health, Education, and Welfare
  • History of Economic Thought
  • International Economics
  • Labour and Demographic Economics
  • Law and Economics
  • Macroeconomics and Monetary Economics
  • Microeconomics
  • Public Economics
  • Urban, Rural, and Regional Economics
  • Welfare Economics
  • Browse content in Education
  • Adult Education and Continuous Learning
  • Care and Counselling of Students
  • Early Childhood and Elementary Education
  • Educational Equipment and Technology
  • Educational Strategies and Policy
  • Higher and Further Education
  • Organization and Management of Education
  • Philosophy and Theory of Education
  • Schools Studies
  • Secondary Education
  • Teaching of a Specific Subject
  • Teaching of Specific Groups and Special Educational Needs
  • Teaching Skills and Techniques
  • Browse content in Environment
  • Applied Ecology (Social Science)
  • Climate Change
  • Conservation of the Environment (Social Science)
  • Environmentalist Thought and Ideology (Social Science)
  • Management of Land and Natural Resources (Social Science)
  • Natural Disasters (Environment)
  • Pollution and Threats to the Environment (Social Science)
  • Social Impact of Environmental Issues (Social Science)
  • Sustainability
  • Browse content in Human Geography
  • Cultural Geography
  • Economic Geography
  • Political Geography
  • Browse content in Interdisciplinary Studies
  • Communication Studies
  • Museums, Libraries, and Information Sciences
  • Browse content in Politics
  • African Politics
  • Asian Politics
  • Chinese Politics
  • Comparative Politics
  • Conflict Politics
  • Elections and Electoral Studies
  • Environmental Politics
  • Ethnic Politics
  • European Union
  • Foreign Policy
  • Gender and Politics
  • Human Rights and Politics
  • Indian Politics
  • International Relations
  • International Organization (Politics)
  • Irish Politics
  • Latin American Politics
  • Middle Eastern Politics
  • Political Methodology
  • Political Communication
  • Political Philosophy
  • Political Sociology
  • Political Behaviour
  • Political Economy
  • Political Institutions
  • Political Theory
  • Politics and Law
  • Politics of Development
  • Public Administration
  • Public Policy
  • Qualitative Political Methodology
  • Quantitative Political Methodology
  • Regional Political Studies
  • Russian Politics
  • Security Studies
  • State and Local Government
  • UK Politics
  • US Politics
  • Browse content in Regional and Area Studies
  • African Studies
  • Asian Studies
  • East Asian Studies
  • Japanese Studies
  • Latin American Studies
  • Middle Eastern Studies
  • Native American Studies
  • Scottish Studies
  • Browse content in Research and Information
  • Research Methods
  • Browse content in Social Work
  • Addictions and Substance Misuse
  • Adoption and Fostering
  • Care of the Elderly
  • Child and Adolescent Social Work
  • Couple and Family Social Work
  • Direct Practice and Clinical Social Work
  • Emergency Services
  • Human Behaviour and the Social Environment
  • International and Global Issues in Social Work
  • Mental and Behavioural Health
  • Social Justice and Human Rights
  • Social Policy and Advocacy
  • Social Work and Crime and Justice
  • Social Work Macro Practice
  • Social Work Practice Settings
  • Social Work Research and Evidence-based Practice
  • Welfare and Benefit Systems
  • Browse content in Sociology
  • Childhood Studies
  • Community Development
  • Comparative and Historical Sociology
  • Disability Studies
  • Economic Sociology
  • Gender and Sexuality
  • Gerontology and Ageing
  • Health, Illness, and Medicine
  • Marriage and the Family
  • Migration Studies
  • Occupations, Professions, and Work
  • Organizations
  • Population and Demography
  • Race and Ethnicity
  • Social Theory
  • Social Movements and Social Change
  • Social Research and Statistics
  • Social Stratification, Inequality, and Mobility
  • Sociology of Religion
  • Sociology of Education
  • Sport and Leisure
  • Urban and Rural Studies
  • Browse content in Warfare and Defence
  • Defence Strategy, Planning, and Research
  • Land Forces and Warfare
  • Military Administration
  • Military Life and Institutions
  • Naval Forces and Warfare
  • Other Warfare and Defence Issues
  • Peace Studies and Conflict Resolution
  • Weapons and Equipment

Fiscal Policy and Public Financial Management

Fiscal Policy and Public Financial Management

Vice-Chairman

Director and Professor

ORCID logo

  • Cite Icon Cite
  • Permissions Icon Permissions

Over time, the scope of Public Finance, as a branch of economics, has expanded with the changing role of governments. From both positive and normative perspectives, this subject is no longer confined to the understanding of public revenue/taxation, public expenditure, and public debt. New areas of research on the subject that have gained critical relevance are issues related to climate finance and climate change, environmental federalism, and discussion on global public good having trans-jurisdictional implications. On public financial management, several new areas have emerged and become relevant for policy. The understanding of fiscal transparency, legislative control over borrowing, and establishing independent fiscal institutions such as ‘fiscal councils’ are important areas of research that have emerged. This book is a collection of essays dealing with evolving frontiers of research on the subject. Specific themes covered in this book are issues related to direct and indirect taxes, tax evasion, public expenditure and debt, fiscal federalism, fiscal transparency, budget management, environmental federalism, climate change and climate finance, and public sector investment appraisals. The array of issues covered in this book provide important analytical insights into the complexity and challenges of fiscal management in India and emerging issues in public financial management, including climate finance.

Personal account

  • Sign in with email/username & password
  • Get email alerts
  • Save searches
  • Purchase content
  • Activate your purchase/trial code
  • Add your ORCID iD

Institutional access

Sign in with a library card.

  • Sign in with username/password
  • Recommend to your librarian
  • Institutional account management
  • Get help with access

Access to content on Oxford Academic is often provided through institutional subscriptions and purchases. If you are a member of an institution with an active account, you may be able to access content in one of the following ways:

IP based access

Typically, access is provided across an institutional network to a range of IP addresses. This authentication occurs automatically, and it is not possible to sign out of an IP authenticated account.

Choose this option to get remote access when outside your institution. Shibboleth/Open Athens technology is used to provide single sign-on between your institution’s website and Oxford Academic.

  • Click Sign in through your institution.
  • Select your institution from the list provided, which will take you to your institution's website to sign in.
  • When on the institution site, please use the credentials provided by your institution. Do not use an Oxford Academic personal account.
  • Following successful sign in, you will be returned to Oxford Academic.

If your institution is not listed or you cannot sign in to your institution’s website, please contact your librarian or administrator.

Enter your library card number to sign in. If you cannot sign in, please contact your librarian.

Society Members

Society member access to a journal is achieved in one of the following ways:

Sign in through society site

Many societies offer single sign-on between the society website and Oxford Academic. If you see ‘Sign in through society site’ in the sign in pane within a journal:

  • Click Sign in through society site.
  • When on the society site, please use the credentials provided by that society. Do not use an Oxford Academic personal account.

If you do not have a society account or have forgotten your username or password, please contact your society.

Sign in using a personal account

Some societies use Oxford Academic personal accounts to provide access to their members. See below.

A personal account can be used to get email alerts, save searches, purchase content, and activate subscriptions.

Some societies use Oxford Academic personal accounts to provide access to their members.

Viewing your signed in accounts

Click the account icon in the top right to:

  • View your signed in personal account and access account management features.
  • View the institutional accounts that are providing access.

Signed in but can't access content

Oxford Academic is home to a wide variety of products. The institutional subscription may not cover the content that you are trying to access. If you believe you should have access to that content, please contact your librarian.

For librarians and administrators, your personal account also provides access to institutional account management. Here you will find options to view and activate subscriptions, manage institutional settings and access options, access usage statistics, and more.

Our books are available by subscription or purchase to libraries and institutions.

  • About Oxford Academic
  • Publish journals with us
  • University press partners
  • What we publish
  • New features  
  • Open access
  • Rights and permissions
  • Accessibility
  • Advertising
  • Media enquiries
  • Oxford University Press
  • Oxford Languages
  • University of Oxford

Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University's objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide

  • Copyright Š 2024 Oxford University Press
  • Cookie settings
  • Cookie policy
  • Privacy policy
  • Legal notice

This Feature Is Available To Subscribers Only

Sign In or Create an Account

This PDF is available to Subscribers Only

For full access to this pdf, sign in to an existing account, or purchase an annual subscription.

fiscal policy essay

Reference Library

Collections

  • See what's new
  • All Resources
  • Student Resources
  • Assessment Resources
  • Teaching Resources
  • CPD Courses
  • Livestreams

Study notes, videos, interactive activities and more!

Economics news, insights and enrichment

Currated collections of free resources

Browse resources by topic

  • All Economics Resources

Resource Selections

Currated lists of resources

Study Notes

IB Economics - Evaluation of Fiscal Policy

Last updated 28 Aug 2024

  • Share on Facebook
  • Share on Twitter
  • Share by Email

This study note for IB economics provides a concise Evaluation of Fiscal Policy

Fiscal policy is a key tool in government macroeconomic management, involving the use of government spending and taxation to influence economic activity. Its effectiveness, however, is subject to various factors, including the ability to target specific sectors, its impact on aggregate demand (AD), and its limitations, such as time lags, political constraints, and the phenomenon of crowding out. This note will explore these dimensions in depth, using real-world examples to illustrate key points.

Key Aspects of Fiscal Policy Evaluation

1. Ability to Target Sectors of the Economy

  • Targeted Interventions: Fiscal policy can be tailored to address specific sectors or regions. For instance, in a recession, governments may increase spending on infrastructure projects in areas with high unemployment.
  • The U.S. government’s response to the 2008 financial crisis included targeted bailouts for the automotive industry (e.g., General Motors and Chrysler).
  • In 2020, during the COVID-19 pandemic, many countries introduced sector-specific support, such as subsidies for the hospitality industry.

Evaluation:

  • Strength: Highly effective in addressing sectoral imbalances and promoting structural changes.
  • Weakness: Requires accurate data and timely decisions; otherwise, it may result in misallocation of resources or neglect of other crucial areas.

2. Direct Impact on Aggregate Demand

  • Mechanism: Fiscal policy directly influences AD through government spending (G) and taxation (T). An increase in G or a decrease in T leads to higher AD.
  • Multiplier Effect: The impact is magnified through the fiscal multiplier, where an initial increase in spending leads to a greater overall increase in economic activity.
  • The U.S. stimulus packages during the COVID-19 pandemic injected trillions of dollars into the economy, directly boosting AD.
  • Japan’s extensive fiscal stimulus in the 1990s aimed to revive its stagnating economy by increasing government spending.
  • Strength: Direct and immediate impact on boosting AD, particularly useful during economic downturns.
  • Weakness: The effectiveness depends on the size of the multiplier, which can vary depending on the state of the economy (e.g., higher in a recession than in a boom).

3. Effectiveness in Promoting Economic Activity in a Recession

  • Counter-Cyclical Policy: During a recession, expansionary fiscal policy (increasing G or decreasing T) can mitigate the downturn by stimulating AD.
  • Automatic Stabilizers: Features like unemployment benefits automatically increase government spending in a recession, supporting incomes without the need for new policy decisions.
  • The European Union’s recovery fund, launched in response to the COVID-19 pandemic, was designed to boost economic activity across member states.
  • The New Deal programs during the Great Depression in the U.S. significantly expanded government spending to promote recovery.
  • Strength: Essential in reducing the depth and duration of recessions.
  • Weakness: Can lead to large budget deficits and increasing public debt, particularly if the recession is prolonged.

4. Time Lags

  • Recognition Lag: The time it takes to identify that a fiscal intervention is needed.
  • Decision Lag: The time required for policymakers to agree on and implement fiscal measures.
  • Implementation Lag: The time taken to execute the fiscal policy and for it to start affecting the economy.
  • During the 2008 financial crisis, it took several months for many countries to design and implement stimulus packages.
  • In some developing countries, bureaucratic inefficiencies further extend implementation lags, reducing the effectiveness of fiscal policy.
  • Weakness: Significant time lags can reduce the effectiveness of fiscal policy, especially in fast-moving economic crises. By the time policy takes effect, the economic situation may have changed.

5. Political Constraints

  • Political Consensus: Fiscal policy often requires approval from legislative bodies, which can be difficult to obtain, particularly in politically polarized environments.
  • Electoral Cycles: Governments might favor policies that yield short-term gains at the expense of long-term stability, influenced by upcoming elections.
  • The U.S. government shutdowns in recent years illustrate how political gridlock can delay fiscal measures.
  • In Europe, the austerity measures post-2008 crisis were heavily influenced by political considerations, leading to significant public unrest.
  • Weakness: Political constraints can delay or distort fiscal policy, making it less effective or even counterproductive.

6. Crowding Out

  • Concept: Increased government spending might lead to higher interest rates, which can reduce private investment—a phenomenon known as crowding out.
  • Partial vs. Full Crowding Out: In extreme cases, government borrowing can fully offset private investment, negating the impact of fiscal stimulus.
  • In the 1980s, the U.S. government’s increased defense spending under President Reagan led to higher interest rates, which crowded out private investment.
  • In the Eurozone, countries with high public debt like Italy and Greece faced higher borrowing costs, which discouraged private investment.
  • Weakness: Crowding out reduces the effectiveness of fiscal policy, particularly in an economy near full capacity. However, during recessions, when private sector demand is low, crowding out is less of a concern.

7. Inability to Deal with Supply-Side Causes of Instability

  • Focus on Demand: Fiscal policy primarily targets AD, making it less effective in addressing supply-side issues like productivity growth, labor market inefficiencies, or technological advancements.
  • Supply-Side Policies: Issues like low productivity, rigid labor markets, or inadequate infrastructure often require supply-side interventions, such as deregulation, tax incentives for investment, or education and training programs.
  • The Japanese economy’s stagnation, despite repeated fiscal stimuli, highlights the limitations of fiscal policy in addressing underlying supply-side weaknesses.
  • In many developing countries, poor infrastructure limits the effectiveness of fiscal spending aimed at boosting economic activity.
  • Weakness: Fiscal policy alone cannot resolve supply-side constraints, which may limit its long-term effectiveness in promoting sustainable economic growth.

Glossary of Key Terms

  • Aggregate Demand (AD): The total demand for goods and services in an economy at a given overall price level and in a given period.
  • Automatic Stabilizers: Economic policies and programs that automatically adjust to counterbalance economic fluctuations, such as unemployment benefits.
  • Crowding Out: The reduction in private investment that occurs when increased government borrowing leads to higher interest rates.
  • Fiscal Multiplier: The ratio of a change in national income to the change in government spending that causes it.
  • Fiscal Policy: Government policies regarding taxation and spending to influence economic conditions.
  • Implementation Lag: The delay between the decision to use fiscal policy and its actual impact on the economy.
  • Recognition Lag: The time it takes for policymakers to recognize the need for fiscal intervention.
  • Supply-Side Policies: Measures aimed at increasing productive capacity by improving the efficiency of markets and reducing costs of production.

Possible IB Economics Essay-Style Questions

  • Discuss with reference to real-world examples.
  • Consider factors such as time lags, crowding out, and supply-side issues.
  • Analyze how political considerations can influence the design and implementation of fiscal measures.
  • Use examples to explore how targeted government spending can address sector-specific issues.

Real-World Data / Figures

  • U.S. COVID-19 Fiscal Response: The U.S. government passed stimulus packages totaling over $5 trillion in response to the COVID-19 pandemic, leading to a significant but uneven recovery.
  • EU Recovery Fund: The European Union’s €750 billion recovery fund aimed to support member states' economies, with a focus on digitalization and green energy.
  • Japan's Public Debt: Japan's public debt reached 266% of GDP in 2023, partly due to repeated fiscal stimulus efforts over decades.

Retrieval Questions for A-Level Students

  • What is fiscal policy, and how does it affect aggregate demand?
  • Explain the concept of the fiscal multiplier.
  • How can fiscal policy be used to target specific sectors of the economy?
  • What are the time lags associated with fiscal policy, and why are they important?
  • Discuss the concept of crowding out and its impact on fiscal policy effectiveness.
  • Why might fiscal policy be less effective in dealing with supply-side causes of economic instability?
  • Provide an example of political constraints affecting fiscal policy in the real world.
  • How do automatic stabilizers work in a recession?
  • In what ways might fiscal policy contribute to long-term economic growth?
  • What are the potential downsides of using fiscal policy to address a recession?
  • Fiscal Policy
  • Crowding Out
  • Crowding in
  • Fiscal Multiplier
  • Implementation Lag

You might also like

Macroeconomic objectives and macro stability.

fiscal policy essay

Key Decisions in the July 2015 Budget

9th July 2015

Fiscal Policy Update: UK Government Spending 2015-16

24th March 2016

fiscal policy essay

10 question multi-choice quiz on Demand and Supply-Side Policies

20th April 2017

Fiscal Policy in the UK - Key Facts in 2018

Topic Videos

Fiscal and Monetary Policy - Connection Wall Activity

Quizzes & Activities

The fiscal multiplier of $2 trillion of stimulus spending

15th January 2021

The Mini Budget - A Chancellor Risking Financial Instability

23rd September 2022

Our subjects

  • › Criminology
  • › Economics
  • › Geography
  • › Health & Social Care
  • › Psychology
  • › Sociology
  • › Teaching & learning resources
  • › Student revision workshops
  • › Online student courses
  • › CPD for teachers
  • › Livestreams
  • › Teaching jobs

Boston House, 214 High Street, Boston Spa, West Yorkshire, LS23 6AD Tel: 01937 848885

  • › Contact us
  • › Terms of use
  • › Privacy & cookies

© 2002-2024 Tutor2u Limited. Company Reg no: 04489574. VAT reg no 816865400.

International Spillovers of U.S. Fiscal Challenges

Expansionary fiscal policies have increased significantly following the subprime crisis in 2007 and the COVID-19 crisis, leading to fiscal dominance concerns, where a growing share of monetary authorities may be forced to deviate from policy targets to accommodate fiscal policies. Meanwhile, peripheral economies are constantly influenced by monetary and fiscal conditions in center economies, with the United States (U.S.) as the predominant force. In light of these developments, we examine the potential international spillovers from U.S. inflationary spells and growing fiscal concerns to the policy interest rates in Emerging Market Economies (EMEs) and Developed Economies (DEs). We introduce a new index of fiscal dominance concerns using Principal Components Analysis, and extend the concept to an international perspective, as opposed to previous literature examining fiscal dominance in a domestic environment. The results are confirmed by robustness analysis and show that greater U.S. fiscal challenges affect negatively the policy rates in both EMEs and DEs, with a greater impact observed in EMEs. Moreover, a low degree of financial repression is associated with more significant spillover effects from greater U.S. fiscal challenges.

An earlier version of this paper was presented at the economics division of LinkĂśping University, Sweden. The authors are deeply grateful to Bo SjĂś, Donghyun Park, Jamel S., Ayhan Kose, Franziska Ohnsorge, and Naotaka Sugawara for sharing the fiscal space data. Joshua Aizenman gratefully acknowledges the financial support of the Dockson Chair at the University of Southern California The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research and the Asian Development Bank.

MARC RIS BibTeΧ

Download Citation Data

More from NBER

In addition to working papers , the NBER disseminates affiliates’ latest findings through a range of free periodicals — the NBER Reporter , the NBER Digest , the Bulletin on Retirement and Disability , the Bulletin on Health , and the Bulletin on Entrepreneurship  — as well as online conference reports , video lectures , and interviews .

2024, 16th Annual Feldstein Lecture, Cecilia E. Rouse," Lessons for Economists from the Pandemic" cover slide

Next IAS

  • भञडञ : हिंदी
  • Classroom Courses
  • Our Selections
  • Student Login
  • About NEXT IAS
  • Director’s Desk
  • Advisory Panel
  • Faculty Panel
  • General Studies Courses
  • Optional Courses
  • Interview Guidance Program
  • Postal Courses
  • Test Series
  • Current Affairs
  • Student Portal

NEXT IAS

  • Prelims Analytica
  • CSE (P) 2024 Solutions
  • Pre Cum Main Foundation Courses
  • 1 Year GSPM Foundation Course
  • 2 Year Integrated GSPM Foundation Course: Elevate
  • 3 Year Integrated GSPM Foundation Course: EDGE
  • 2 Year GSPM Foundation with Advanced Integrated Mentorship (FAIM)
  • Mentorship Courses
  • 1 Year Advanced Integrated Mentorship (AIM)
  • Early Start GS Courses
  • 1 Year GS First Step
  • Mains Specific
  • Mains Advance Course (MAC) 2024
  • Essay Guidance Program cum Test Series 2024
  • Ethics Enhancer Course 2024
  • Prelims Specific
  • Weekly Current Affairs Course 2025
  • Current Affairs for Prelims (CAP) 2025
  • CSAT Course 2025
  • CSAT EDGE 2025
  • Optional Foundation Courses
  • Mathematics
  • Anthropology
  • Political Science and International Relations (PSIR)
  • Optional Advance Courses
  • Political Science & International Relations (PSIR)
  • Civil Engineering
  • Electrical Engineering
  • Mechanical Engineering
  • Interview Guidance Programme / Personality Test Training Program
  • GS + CSAT Postal Courses
  • Current Affairs Magazine – Annual Subscription
  • GS+CSAT Postal Study Course
  • First Step Postal Course
  • Postal Study Course for Optional Subjects
  • Prelims Test Series for CSE 2025 (Offline/Online)
  • General Studies
  • GS Mains Test Series for CSE 2024
  • Mains Test Series (Optional)
  • PSIR (Political Science & International Relations)
  • Paarth PSIR
  • PSIR Answer Writing Program
  • PSIR PRO Plus Test Series
  • Mathematics Yearlong Test Series (MYTS) 2024
  • Indian Economic Services
  • ANUBHAV (All India Open Mock Test)
  • ANUBHAV Prelims (GS + CSAT)
  • ANUBHAV Mains
  • Headlines of the Day
  • Daily Current Affairs
  • Editorial Analysis
  • Monthly MCQ Compilation
  • Monthly Current Affairs Magazine
  • Previous Year Papers
  • Down to Earth
  • Kurukshetra
  • Union Budget
  • Economic Survey
  • Download NCERTs
  • NIOS Study Material
  • Beyond Classroom
  • Toppers’ Copies
  • Indian Economy

Fiscal Policy in India: Meaning, Objectives, Instruments & Types

Fiscal Policy

Fiscal Policy in India is the cornerstone of its economic strategy, which steers the country through various phases of growth, development, and challenges. It plays crucial role in shaping the nation’s development trajectory, influencing its macroeconomic stability, and addressing socio-economic challenges. This article of NEXT IAS delves into the nuances of Fiscal Policy in India, including its meaning, objectives, instruments, types and other aspects.

Definition of Fiscal Policy

Fiscal Policy refers to government policy in respect of public expenditure, taxation and public debt. It is the means by which the government adjusts its spending levels and tax rates to monitor and influence a nation’s economy.

Fiscal policy is based on the principles of Keynesian economics, which basically states that governments can influence macroeconomic productivity levels by increasing or decreasing tax levels and public spending.

Fiscal Policy

Objectives of Fiscal Policy in India

Some of the main objectives of fiscal policy in India can be seen as follows:

  • To mobilise additional resources into socially necessary lines of development
  • To achieve and maintain economic stability
  • To stabilize the price level.
  • To maintain the growth rate of the economy.
  • To maintain equilibrium in the balance of payments.
  • To raise standard of living of the citizens of the country.
  • To reduce extreme inequality in income and wealth
  • To provide the necessary incentives to the private sector for its healthy growth. etc

Tools of Fiscal Policy

Major tools of fiscal policy used by the government are as follows:

Public Expenditure

It includes subsidies, transfer payments including welfare programs, public works projects and government salaries. By increasing or decreasing its spending, the government can directly influence economic activity. For example, more government spending can increase demand, leading to higher output and employment.

The government can influence economic activity through its taxation policy. By reducing taxes, the government leaves individuals and businesses with more income to spend and invest, which can boost economic growth. Conversely, increasing taxes can help cool down an overheated economy by reducing the amount of disposable income available.

Further Reading: Taxation System in India

Public Borrowing

Public borrowing refers to the means by which governments finance their expenditures that exceed tax revenues. Under it, the government raises money from the domestic population or from abroad through instruments such as bonds, NSC, Kisan Vikas Patra, etc. Public borrowing is a common practice used to fund public services, infrastructure projects, welfare programs, and to manage the country’s fiscal policy.

Other Measures

Other fiscal measures adopted by the government include:

  • Rationing and price control
  • Regulation of wages
  • Increase the production of goods and services.

Difference between Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy

It is a macro-economic policy used by the government to adjust its spending levels and tax rates to monitor and a nation’s economyIt is a macro-economic policy used by the Central Bank to influence money supply and interest rates.
Controlled by the GovernmentControlled by the Central Bank
To influence the economic conditionTo influence the money supply and interest rates.
Public Expenditure, Taxation, Public Borrowing etcBank Rate, Cash Reserve Ratio, Statutory Liquidity Ratio etc.

Difference between Fiscal Policy and Monetary Policy

Types of Fiscal Policies

Based on the economic conditions and the objectives that governments aim to achieve, fiscal policy can be categorized into three main types

Fiscal policy that increases aggregate demand directly through an increase in government spending is called expansionary.Fiscal policy that reduces demand via lower spending is called contractionary or tight.A neutral fiscal policy refers to a strategy by which the government’s budget is designed to neither stimulate nor restrain economic growth.
The objective of Expansionary Fiscal Policy is to reduce unemployment and also results in better GDP.The objective of Contractionary Fiscal Policy is to reduce inflation.The objective of Neutral Fiscal policy is to maintain the status quo in the economy.
It can cause some inflation.It can trigger some unemployment.It may lead to degradation due to inaction in prevailing conditions.
This type of policy is usually undertaken during recessions to increase the level of economic activity.This type of policy is usually undertaken during inflationary periods to control excess money supply.This type of fiscal policy is usually followed when an economy is in equilibrium.

Cyclicality of the Fiscal Policy

The cyclicality of the fiscal policy refers to a change in direction of government expenditure and taxes based on economic conditions and fluctuations in economic growth.

There are two types of cyclical fiscal policies:

Counter-Cyclical Fiscal Policy

It refers to the steps taken by the government that go against the direction of the economic or business cycle.

  • For example , in a recession or slowdown, the government, usually, takes the route of expansionary fiscal policy. This increases expenditure and reduces taxes to create a demand that can drive an economic boom. This increases the consumption potential of the economy and helps soften the recession.

Pro-Cyclical Fiscal Policy

It refers to the type of fiscal policy wherein the government reinforces the business cycle by being expansionary during good times and contractionary during recessions.

  • Pursuing a pro-cyclical fiscal policy is generally regarded as dangerous as it could raise macroeconomic volatility, depress investment, hamper growth and harm the poor. For example, adopting Contractionary Fiscal Policy during a recession will reduce the government expenditure and increase the taxes. This will further decrease the consumption potential of the economy and deepen the recession.

Related Concepts

Fiscal deficit.

Fiscal Deficit refers to the gap between the government’s total expenditure in a given financial year and its total revenue (excluding borrowings) in the same financial year. It is expressed as a percentage of the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) and is an indicator of the government’s financial health.

Fiscal Consolidation

Fiscal consolidation is a process where government’s fiscal health is improved by reducing fiscal deficit to levels which is manageable and bearable for the economy. Improved tax revenue realization and better aligned expenditure are important components of fiscal consolidation.

Fiscal Drag

Fiscal drag is an economic term whereby inflation or income growth moves taxpayers into higher tax brackets. It occurs mainly due to Progressive Taxation, whereby individuals are moved into higher tax brackets because of inflation or increased income.

Fiscal Neutrality

Fiscal neutrality is when a government taxing, spending, or borrowing decision has or is intended to have no net effect on the economy. Any new spending introduced by a policy change that is fiscally neutral in this sense is expected to be entirely offset by additional revenues generated. Thus, Fiscal Neutrality creates a condition where demand is neither stimulated nor diminished by taxation and government spending.

Crowding Out Effect

The crowding out effect is an economic theory suggesting that increased government spending leads to a reduction in private sector spending. This phenomenon occurs because the resources used by the government must come from somewhere, typically through increased taxation or borrowing. Thus, the private sector is left with lesser resources to invest.

Pump Priming

Pump priming is the action taken to stimulate an economy usually during a recessionary period, through government spending, and interest rate and tax reductions. Pump priming involves introducing relatively small amounts of government funds into a depressed economy in order to spur growth.

Economic Stimulus

An economic stimulus is the use of monetary or fiscal policy changes to kick start growth during a recession. Governments can accomplish this by using methods such as lowering interest rates, increasing government spending and quantitative easing, to name a few. In the wake of COVID-19 Pandemic, the Government announced 3 tranches of economic stimulus under the Atma Nirbhar Bharat Programme.

Frequently Asked Questions (FAQs) on Fiscal Policy in India

What is fiscal consolidation.

Fiscal Consolidation refers to improving government’s fiscal health by reducing fiscal deficit.

Who Prepares Fiscal Policy in India?

Fiscal Policy in India is formulated by the Finance Ministry of the Central or State Governments.

What are the three types of Fiscal Policy?

Based on the objective, there are three types of fiscal policies – Expansionary, Contractionary and Neutral .

RELATED ARTICLES MORE FROM AUTHOR

Bad bank: meaning, needs, framework & more, payment banks: meaning, features & more, small finance banks (sfb): meaning, features & more, insolvency and bankruptcy code 2016 (ibc 2016), non performing assets (npas): causes, impacts & resolution, nationalisation of banks in india, leave a reply cancel reply.

Save my name, email, and website in this browser for the next time I comment.

Featured Post

NEXT IAS

NEXT IAS (Delhi)

Old rajinder nagar.

  • 27-B, Pusa Road, Metro Pillar no.118, Near Karol Bagh Metro, New Delhi-110060

Mukherjee Nagar

  • 1422, Main Mukherjee Nagar Road. Near Batra Cinema New Delhi-110009

fiscal policy essay

NEXT IAS (Jaipur)

  • NEXT IAS - Plot No - 6 & 7, 3rd Floor, Sree Gopal Nagar, Gopalpura Bypass, Above Zudio Showroom Jaipur (Rajasthan) - 302015

fiscal policy essay

NEXT IAS (Prayagraj)

  • 31/31, Sardar Patel Marg, Civil Lines, Prayagraj, Uttar Pradesh - 211001

fiscal policy essay

NEXT IAS (Bhopal)

  • Plot No. 46 Zone - 2 M.P Nagar Bhopal - 462011
  • 8827664612 ,

telegram

World Food Day – Strike to Hunger

  • Search Search Please fill out this field.

Monetary Policy

Fiscal policy, key differences, the bottom line.

  • Government & Policy

Monetary Policy vs. Fiscal Policy: What's the Difference?

fiscal policy essay

  • Federal Reserve System: What It Is and How It Works
  • Central Bank
  • Central Banks and Interest Rates
  • Financial Regulators
  • Who Determines Interest Rates?
  • Monetary Policy vs. Fiscal Policy CURRENT ARTICLE
  • 1913 Federal Reserve Act
  • How the Federal Reserve was Formed
  • Federal Reserve Board
  • Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC)
  • Why Is the Federal Reserve Independent?
  • What Do the Federal Reserve Banks Do?
  • The Federal Reserve Chair's Responsibilities
  • How the Federal Reserve Creates Money
  • Federal Reserve Balance Sheet
  • Reserve Requirements
  • Reserve Ratio Definition
  • Interest Rate Cuts and Consumers
  • Fed Fund Rate Hikes and the US Dollar
  • Open Market Operations
  • Tight Monetary Policy
  • Expansionary Policy
  • Taylor's Rule

Monetary Policy vs. Fiscal Policy: An Overview

Monetary policy and fiscal policy refer to the two most widely recognized tools used to influence a nation's economic activity. Monetary policy is primarily concerned with the management of interest rates and the total supply of money in circulation and is generally carried out by central banks , such as the U.S. Federal Reserve (Fed) . Fiscal policy is a collective term for the taxing and spending actions of governments. In the United States, the national fiscal policy is determined by the executive and legislative branches of the government. 

Key Takeaways

  • Both monetary and fiscal policy are macroeconomic tools used to manage or stimulate the economy.
  • Monetary policy addresses interest rates and the supply of money in circulation, and it is generally managed by a central bank.
  • Fiscal policy addresses taxation and government spending, and it is generally determined by government legislation.
  • Monetary policy and fiscal policy together have great influence over a nation's economy, its businesses, and its consumers.

Central banks typically use monetary policy to either stimulate an economy or to check its growth. By incentivizing individuals and businesses to borrow and spend, the monetary policy aims to spur economic activity. Conversely, by restricting spending and incentivizing savings, monetary policy can act as a brake on inflation and other issues associated with an overheated economy.

The Fed frequently uses three different policy tools to influence the economy:

  • Open Market Operations: Open market operations are carried out on a daily basis when the Fed buys and sells U.S. government bonds to either inject money into the economy or pull money out of circulation.
  • Reserve Requirements: By setting the reserve ratio , or the percentage of deposits that banks are required to keep in reserve, the Fed directly influences the amount of money created when banks make loans.
  • Discount Rate: The Fed also can target changes in the discount rate , which is the interest rate it charges on loans it makes to financial institutions. This tool is intended to impact short-term interest rates across the entire economy.

Monetary policy is more of a blunt tool in terms of expanding and contracting the money supply to influence inflation and growth and it has less impact on the real economy. For example, the Fed was aggressive during the Great Depression . Its actions prevented deflation and economic collapse but did not generate significant economic growth to reverse the lost output and jobs.

Contractionary vs. Expansionary Monetary Policy

Monetary policies can be either contractionary or expansionary. Implementing one type of policy depends on the current economic climate and the ultimate goals.

  • Contractionary Monetary Policy: Central banks will use contractionary monetary policies when inflation becomes a concern as the economy gets overheated. In this case, prices rise as purchasing power drops.
  • Expansionary Monetary Policy: This type of monetary policy is used to help spur growth when can there's a recession or slowdown. Expansionary monetary policies have limited effects on growth by increasing asset prices and lowering the costs of borrowing, making companies more profitable.

Monetary policy seeks to spark economic activity, while fiscal policy seeks to address either total spending, the total composition of spending, or both.

Fiscal policy refers to the steps that governments take in order to influence the direction of the economy. But rather than encouraging or restricting spending by businesses and consumers, fiscal policy aims to target the total level of spending, the total composition of spending, or both in an economy.

The two most widely used means of affecting fiscal policy are:

  • Government Spending Policies: Governments can increase the amount of money they spend if they believe there is not enough business activity in an economy. This is often referred to as stimulus spending. They can borrow money by issuing debt securities (like government bonds) if there are not enough tax receipts to pay for the spending increases, allowing them to accumulate debt. This is referred to as deficit spending .
  • Government Tax Policies: By increasing taxes, governments pull money out of the economy and slow business activity. Fiscal policy is typically used when the government seeks to stimulate the economy. It might lower taxes or offer tax rebates in an effort to encourage economic growth. Influencing economic outcomes via fiscal policy is one of the core tenets of Keynesian economics .

When a government spends money or changes tax policy, it must choose where to spend or what to tax. In doing so, government fiscal policy can target specific communities, industries, investments, or commodities to either favor or discourage production—sometimes, its actions are based on considerations that are not entirely economic. For this reason, fiscal policy is often hotly debated among economists and political observers.

Fiscal policy essentially targets aggregate demand . Companies also benefit as they see increased revenues. However, if the economy is near full capacity, expansionary fiscal policy risks sparking inflation. This inflation eats away at the margins of certain corporations in competitive industries that may not be able to easily pass on costs to customers; it also eats away at the funds of people on a fixed income .

Contractionary vs. Expansionary Fiscal Policy

Governments can execute their fiscal policies through contractionary or expansionary measures:

  • Contractionary Fiscal Policy: Governments can turn to contractionary measures to slow down the economy and curb inflation . These steps include raising taxes and reducing government spending. It isn't uncommon that a recession follows to bring balance back to the economy.
  • Expansionary Fiscal Policy: This is commonly done during recessions to encourage people to spend. Governments often turn to measures like stimulus checks issued to taxpayers. They may also increase government spending as a way to boost employment. Expansionary fiscal policies are commonly associated with deficit spending.

In comparing the two, fiscal policy generally has a greater impact on consumers than monetary policy, as it can lead to increased employment and income.

While the overall goal of monetary and fiscal policy is generally the same—to influence the economy—there are inherent differences between the two.

Among the key differences between monetary and fiscal policy is the party responsible for carrying them out. Monetary policy is carried out by a nation's central bank, such as the Fed in the U.S., the Bank of Canada (BOC) , and the Bank of England. Fiscal policy, on the other hand, is the sole responsibility of a country's government.

The tools that are used are also distinct between the two. While monetary policy relies on open market operations, reserve requirements, and/or the discount rate, fiscal policy involves the use of government spending and/or changes in government tax policies.

What's the Difference Between Monetary and Fiscal Policy?

Monetary and fiscal policy are different tools used to influence a nation's economy. Monetary policy is executed by a country's central bank through open market operations, changing reserve requirements, and the use of its discount rate.

Fiscal policy, on the other hand, is the responsibility of governments. It is evident through changes in government spending and tax collection.

Is Monetary or Fiscal Policy Better?

That depends on who you ask and the type of policy implemented. When central banks lower interest rates by using monetary policy, the cost of borrowing and investment becomes cheaper. This allows consumers to assume more debt and make large purchases. Businesses are also able to invest in their growth.

Fiscal policy, on the other hand, helps increase gross domestic product (GDP) through expansionary tools. This occurs because demand for goods and services increases, which leads to a rise in prices and output.

What Are the Common Goals of Monetary and Fiscal Policy?

Monetary and fiscal policy are two different tools that central banks and governments use to influence the economy. Both are employed to help bring stability to a country's economy. They often work best when they are implemented together, where monetary policy shifts a country's financial markets while fiscal policy affects how much money people have in their pockets.

Both fiscal and monetary policy play a large role in managing the economy and both have direct and indirect impacts on personal and household finances. Fiscal policy involves tax and spending decisions set by the government, and will impact individuals' tax bill or provide them with employment from government projects. Monetary policy is set by the central bank and can boost consumer spending through lower interest rates that make borrowing cheaper on everything from credit cards to mortgages.

Federal Reserve. " Open Market Evaluations ."

International Monetary Fund. " FISCAL POLICY: TAKING AND GIVING AWAY ."

fiscal policy essay

  • Terms of Service
  • Editorial Policy
  • Privacy Policy

Essays on Fiscal policy

We found 13 free papers on fiscal policy, essay examples, explaination of fiscal policy.

Fiscal policy

Fiscal policy can be determined as the use of government spending and taxes In order to alter the Gross Domestic Product (GAP). From the macro perspective, the federal budget is a tool that can shift aggregate demand and thereby alter macroeconomic outcomes. Although fiscal policy can be used to pursue any of the economic goals,…

Policy in Recession

Introduction Recession is said to be an economic issue, that is characterized by general increase in prices of goods and services that is inflation, and at the same time in the economy there is higher levels of unemployment.  Over the last few months ago, what has been observed in the world economy is steep increase…

Monetary Policy in Nigeria 1980- 2008

Over the years, the objectives of monetary policy have remained the attainment of internal and external balance of payments. However, emphasis on techniques/instruments to achieve those objectives have changed over the years. There have been two major phases in the pursuit of monetary policy, namely, before and after 1986. The first phase placed emphasis on…

Is Monetary Policy Superior To Fiscal Policy

Governments across the Earth strive for accomplishing a set of macroeconomic degree economic aims, in which to make a stable platform of economic prosperity. Such aims consist of ; high and stable economic growing ; low unemployment ; low rising prices and, the bar of balance of payments shortages and inordinate exchange rate fluctuations Demand…

Ricardian Equivalence and Keynesian Macroeconomics

Macroeconomics

Explain what is meant by the term Ricardian Equivalence. Does it mean that public debt does not matter? Discuss This work outlines the meaning of Ricardian Equivalence and how it suggests that public debt does not matter to either the government or the society that government is representing. A discussion follows stating this may not…

Fiscal Policy and the Goverment Theory

QUESTION 3 Fiscal policy refers to the government’s handling of the budget. Usually fiscal policy is about spending as much as possible, thereby stimulating the economy,without necessarily raising taxes. In other words Fiscal policy involves the Government changing the levels of Taxation and Govt Spending in order to influence Aggregate Demand (AD) and therefore the…

Ecojagg: Japan Postwar Expansion

Economic Overview Japan started to go industrialised about 80 old ages ago and is now know as the most to the full developed industrial state in Asia and is one of the taking industrialised states in the universe. the celerity of Japan s postwar economic growing has been a slightly singular exclusion in modern economic…

Recession in UK Economy

Acronyms: Gross Domestic Product- Measure of the market value  of goods and services produced by a country. Real income- Income of individuals or the nation which is adjusted for inflation. Aggregate Demand-Total amount of goods and services in the economy at a given overall price level and in a given period. Inflation-The rise in the…

Cadbury PLC Business Analysis of the Company

1. Introduction Cadbury Plc has invariably been in the limelight since August this twelvemonth when its portion monetary value rose by more than 200 pence when Kraft placed its hostile coup d’etat command worth $ 17 billion. Since so other challengers such as Hershey, Ferrero and Nestle have besides made involvement for acquisition of the…

Over-dependence on Global Economy

Over-dependence on Global Economy The growth of the Philippines economy drastically slowed to just 3.6%.the slowdown may have been due to the on-going global crisis, it was markedly slower in comparison to other South-East Asian neighbours. Economic performance figures indicated a contraction in exports and a drop in FDI. The administration further allowed the US…

Frequently Asked Questions about Fiscal policy

Don't hesitate to contact us. We are ready to help you 24/7

fiscal policy essay

Hi, my name is Amy 👋

In case you can't find a relevant example, our professional writers are ready to help you write a unique paper. Just talk to our smart assistant Amy and she'll connect you with the best match.

We use cookies to enhance our website for you. Proceed if you agree to this policy or learn more about it.

  • Essay Database >
  • Essays Examples >
  • Essay Topics

Essays on Fiscal Policy

38 samples on this topic

Crafting a lot of Fiscal Policy papers is an essential part of modern studying, be it in high-school, college, or university. If you can do that unassisted, that's just awesome; yet, other students might not be that skilled, as Fiscal Policy writing can be quite troublesome. The database of free sample Fiscal Policy papers presented below was formed in order to help embattled students rise up to the challenge.

On the one hand, Fiscal Policy essays we publish here precisely demonstrate how a really terrific academic piece of writing should be developed. On the other hand, upon your demand and for an affordable price, a competent essay helper with the relevant academic background can put together a top-notch paper model on Fiscal Policy from scratch.

Essay On Fiscal Health Care Matters

Introduction

Bank Of Ecoville And Monetary Policy Question & Answer Sample

Fiscal policy: free sample essay to follow.

The main goal of the state at all stages of its development is the stabilization of the economy. At the present time, the state actively uses the tools of intervention in the economy. The main 2 types of state intervention in the market economy include fiscal and monetary policies. Fiscal policy has been a key policy tool in addressing the aggregate demand consequences of the financial crisis in the United States. (Follette & Lutz, 2010)

Objectives of fiscal policy as any stabilization (countercyclical) policies aimed at smoothing cyclical fluctuations in the economy are to ensure:

GDP And Fiscal Policy Critical Thinking Sample

Money and prices in the long run and open economies {type) to use as a writing model.

Money and prices in the long run and open economies dictate the financial market. As such, that is why factors such as domestic variables and foreign monetary policies are over-emphasized. Demand for money is thus affected by the domestic variables, which include interest rates, price expectations, and permanent income, among others. As such, this paper explores the financial market to reveal the viable strategies the US can adapt to secure reliable money and prices in an open economy on a long-term basis.

The state of US Financial Market

A-Level Essay On Active Monetary And Fiscal Policy And Increased Government Spending To Fight Recessions For Free Use

Free essay about obama care and how it affects the economy, financial policy, security issuance, and management: research paper you might want to emulate.

Finance is a vast area of discussion that requires one's dedication and interest to understand it better. Under finance, there are major issues like corporate financial policy which has a lot to be studied. The corporate fiscal policy is defined as an innovative corporate finance course that mainly touches on equity and debt management, for example, the descriptions of types of debt and equity, distribution policy and security issuance, for instance, the design of capital structure and securities that controls information problems. The sub-topics in securities and financial policy can be discussed in details as below.

Debt and equity management.

List Of Figures Report Sample

Report for McDonalds

Italy and Russia

Figure 1: GDP per Capita at Constant Prices Figure 2: GDP Growth (Annual %) Figure 3: Inflation Rate CPI Figure 4: Unemployment Rates Figure 5: Policy Interest Rate (%) Figure 6: Russia Interest Rate (%) Figure 7: Current Account Balance in Italy (% of GDP) Figure 8: Current Account Balance in Russia (% of GDP) Figure 9: Russia Interest Rate

List of Tables

An Activist Monetary Policy: Article Review Example

Article review

Inspiring Question & Answer About Main Consequences Inflation

Democracy and free market {type) to use as a writing model.

The Evolution of Economics, Economic Systems and Politics

Proper Research Paper Example About Was Keynes Right?

Mcdonalds fast-food chain: italy and russia: exemplar report to follow, good example of budget deficit and national debt essay, government spending as a means of reducing recession essays example.

Increase Government Spending to Fight Recessions

Introduction Government spending as a recession recovery tool has been the subject of debate numerous times. To date, there is no definitive proof of its success or failure of its application. An active fiscal or a monetary policy is the sum total of the actions taken as a reaction to the current economic conditions; the government chooses to use a specific policy to deal with something in the economy (Mankiw, 2001).

Good Example Of The Costs Of High Unemployment Rate To The Canadian Economy Term Paper

Free essay about how fed saved the economy, expertly written essay on pros and cons of using the local tax base to subsidize nfl stadiums to follow, macro economics assignment: a sample essay for inspiration & mimicking.

Economic management is the most critical function of any government. It requires critical approaches through the adoption of efficient macro-economic policies that lead an economy in the desired direction. Inefficiencies in public policies result in poor economic management, which results in economic problems such as unemployment, inflation, and other forms of economic instabilities (GalĂ­ 98). This essay will answer questions that address some of these economic problems.

Government measures to increase the level of aggregate demand in the economy and their effectiveness

Governments Role: Free Sample Essay To Follow

Canada – a land of opportunity essay template for faster writing.

INDICATORS:

Income level: High Income Population: 35.54 million (“Data” 2014) GDP at market prices (Current US$): $1.785 trillion (“Data” 2014).

GDP per capita (current US$):

$50,230.8 (“Data” 2014). GDP growth (annual %): 2.44 (“Data” 2014). FDI Inflows: $59.6 billion in 2014 (“Trade Policy Review” 5). FDI Outflows: $58.2 billion in 2014 (“Trade Policy Review” 5).

Balance of Payment:

Essay On Macroeconomics

Example of essay on econ 410, acknowledgements: free sample essay to follow.

Abstract / Executive Summary

Free Capital Market Case Study Example

Example of essay on keynes proposal, monetary policy and fiscal policies: research paper you might want to emulate, free essay on governmental and nonprofit organization accounting, fiscal policy: implications from the financial crisis: example essay by an expert writer to follow.

1-How Was The Economy When Obama Took Office? (Unemployment Rate, Inflation, and GDP)

Essay On Capital Funds

Free research paper about japan: international economic research project.

The economy of Japan has seen a downturn with the economic crisis in the year 2008. Every country has been faced with the consequences that resulted in different impacts. The paper will present the economic indicators and overall economic situations in the Japan. The background of the country’s economic policies will be present, with international and regional trade agreements. The focus will be on presenting the specific economic data along with the definitions and interpretations. Further on, the current state of the country’s economy will be examined in the light of trade, fiscal and monetary policy.

Background on the country and recent economic policies

Good Essay On Chinese Banking System Analysis

Chrysler: example research paper by an expert writer to follow, free the effects of fiscal policy on private business investment essay example, free monetary policy and the great recession essay sample.

275 words = 1 page double-spaced

submit your paper

Password recovery email has been sent to [email protected]

Use your new password to log in

You are not register!

By clicking Register, you agree to our Terms of Service and that you have read our Privacy Policy .

Now you can download documents directly to your device!

Check your email! An email with your password has already been sent to you! Now you can download documents directly to your device.

or Use the QR code to Save this Paper to Your Phone

The sample is NOT original!

Short on a deadline?

Don't waste time. Get help with 11% off using code - GETWOWED

No, thanks! I'm fine with missing my deadline

Logo

  • Previous Article

The Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) has enhanced its macroeconomic modeling through the Forecasting and Policy Analysis System (FPAS), transitioning from a multi-equation econometric model to a modernized system centered on the Quarterly Projection Model (QPM). In its new version, the Policy Analysis Model for the Philippines (PAMPh2.0) integrates forward-looking projections, endogenous monetary policy, fiscal and macroprudential considerations, labor dynamics, and addresses complex shocks and policy trade-offs, facilitating effective policy mix determination and supporting real-time policy evaluation. The BSP’s modernization efforts also include refining forecast calendars and strengthening communication channels to accommodate the operationalization of PAMPh2.0. Detailed validation methods ensure empirical consistency. Finally, future refinements will align the model with evolving empirical findings and theoretical insights, ensuring its continued relevance.

  • 1. Introduction

The Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) is upgrading its framework for macroeconomic modeling through the Forecasting and Policy Analysis System (FPAS). While relying on a multi-equation econometric model (MEM), the BSP leans toward a modernized FPAS with a semi-structural Quarterly Projection Model (QPM) at its core in response to the increasing complexity of its operating environment amid global supply shocks in a small open economy particularly vulnerable to sudden and large swings in capital flows and exchange rate volatility. The extended QPM 1 , known as the Policy Analysis Model for the Philippines, version 2.0 (PAMPh2.0) offers forward-looking projections with endogenous monetary policy and extends to include fiscal policy, macrofinancial linkages, labor dynamics, and additional tools like FX interventions. The full operationalization of the model, as this paper will show, could significantly enhance policymakers’ real-time evaluation of decisions, especially in navigating a complex macro-financial landscape, fostering integrated thinking about trade-offs between different policy tools and supporting coordination among the different policies that could foster improved interdepartmental cooperation within the BSP.

The collaborative efforts between the IMF and BSP, facilitated by ICD-led technical assistance (TA) since Spring 2022, have been dedicated to the development and modernization of PAMPh2.0 for its adoption as the BSP’s core medium-term forecasting model. Throughout the TA project, extensions were incorporated gradually, achieving significant milestones such as “conditional forecasting,” preparation and presentation of shadow or mock forecasts (in parallel or ahead of actual, real-time forecasts), and conducting scenario analyses. The continuous enhancement of models and tools has proven invaluable in effectively navigating complex situations, requiring a delicate balance among policy trade-offs and objectives.

The BSP’s modernization effort will extend beyond the core model, implementing reforms for crucial elements of the modernized FPAS. This shall encompass refining the forecast and monetary policy meeting calendar, establishing effective interdepartmental and vertical communication with senior management to facilitate policy deliberations and other system-wide improvements. These efforts are particularly significant in the context of the new PAMPh2.0 and the associated complexities of communication within a multi-policy environment. A clear plan outlining activities leading to the formal adoption of PAMPh2.0 is underway.

The BSP has embarked on enriching its first QPM in response to a new environment characterized by complex and interrelated fundamental and non-fundamental shocks. These included the impact of COVID-19 shocks, Ukraine and commodity price shocks post-COVID-19, global interest rate (Fed tightening) shocks, and destabilizing risk premia and global investor sentiment shifts. It has sought to assess quantitatively how these shocks interact with frictions and characteristics inherent to the Philippines, including financial imperfections like FX market depth and occasionally-binding external debt limits as well as domestic market imperfections and credit channels, to better tailor its policy response. For example, in evaluating risks to anchored inflation expectations, BSP staff has analyzed the impact of exchange rate shocks and supply shocks and conducted policy simulations within the framework of PAMPh2.0. The latter has also encompassed the role of fiscal and macroprudential policy reaction functions to support a coherent monetary and exchange rate regime, while also exploring labor market-wage-related issues, and climate-change considerations.

PAMPh2.0, drawing inspiration from the recently published extended QPM FINEX ( Berg et al., 2023 ), stands out as a state-of-the-art, open-economy New Keynesian general equilibrium model. Inspired by the Integrated Policy Framework (IPF) by the IMF, it explicitly incorporates crucial macro-financial channels, following the microfounded portfolio balance approach by Gabaix and Maggiori (2015) . 2 Although not explicitly categorized as a friction-based, welfare-optimizing framework, PAMPh2.0 analyzes a range of policy tools, extending beyond traditional monetary and fiscal policies to include non-traditional tools such as foreign exchange intervention (FXI), capital flow management measures (CFMs), and macroprudential measures (MPMs). Further, operating within a consistent and systematic policy framework tailored for the Philippines, PAMPh2.0 facilitates the analysis of trade-offs and the determination of efficient policy mixes. Emphasizing its integrated monetary and financial nature, PAMPh2.0 serves as an advanced forecasting model, primarily designed for baseline forecasts, risk analysis, policy scenarios, and simulations. The model, aligning with the operational approach of central banks worldwide, including both advanced economies (AE) and EMDEs, 3 emphasizes reliability and operational efficiency, structured into modules that are straightforward to follow and implement. Acknowledging the importance of clear interpretation, PAMPh2.0 has been specifically designed to simplify the understanding of shocks, generate policy-dependent forecasts, and effectively communicate economic narratives related to forecasts and alternative scenarios.

In asserting its validation, three forecast evaluation methods for PAMPh2.0 have been considered. To begin with, the decomposition of changes in consecutive forecasts, particularly applied in different shadow forecasts, has aimed at enhancing understanding and explanation of forecast variations to policymakers. This could address their interest in discerning how the current forecast differs from the previous one, identifying key drivers, and understanding implications for policy recommendations. Meanwhile, the validation exercise comparing historical forecasts with actual data, while critical, can only be conducted in the future when at least a year’s worth of historical quarterly forecasts are collected, and more elaborate databases are developed. Nonetheless, preparations for such an evaluation are already underway. 4 The aim is to create a robust model that fits the Philippines empirical evidence while maintaining theoretical and macroeconomic consistency within its monetary regime.

Addressing challenges in adopting PAMPh2.0 involves managing communication associated with multiple channels and trade-offs in constructing a narrative for a complex policy mix. Through its consistent framework, PAMPh2.0 can offer a solution in effectively communicating the use of policy tools within more complex regimes. Another hurdle is integrating policies working on different time frames and frequencies, affecting various parts of economic cycles. Coordination challenges also arise as BSP’s departments operate independently, emphasizing the need for integrated views from different departments, guided by the BSP’s Advisory Committee (AC) on Monetary Policy and Monetary Board. Additionally, assessing the size and nature of shocks in real-time presents a critical challenge, suggesting the use of preventive policies (e.g., MPMs) to maintain macro-financial stability. In its effort to foster ownership and draw feedback at an early stage, PAMPh2.0 dissemination both internally and externally 5 has helped further clarify calibration methods, labor and wage dynamics under persistent inflation, model property validation, prioritization of different models’ use for regular forecasting, and better integration of policy and operational frameworks.

Collaborative efforts have effectively addressed crucial gaps, establishing PAMPh2.0 as the preferred core model for policy deliberation at the time of this paper’s publication. Any remaining gaps are not anticipated to significantly impede the operationalization and adoption of PAMPh2.0 in both policy setting and communication. However, being a dynamic model, PAMPh2.0 is expected to undergo future refinements to align with evolving theoretical thinking and empirical findings. With the BSP staff having acquired the necessary skills, the model is well-positioned for refinement and adaptation in response to significant developments in the foreseeable future. Looking ahead, the formal adoption of PAMPh2.0 creates additional opportunities to develop and institutionalize coordination among the monetary, financial supervision, and macroprudential sectors. In its extended form, PAMPh2.0 could serve as a very useful tool for technical staff and policymakers to assess initial conditions and assumptions, quantify policy effects and alternative scenarios, understand trade-offs, ensuring that policy decisions align with the BSP’s long-term objectives.

In the subsequent sections, we delve into the details. Section 2 delineates the essential stylized facts of the Philippines, crucial for motivating the structure of PAMPh2.0 by offering an interpretation of recent economic developments and policy preferences. Readers well-versed in the economy’s structure may opt to bypass this section and proceed directly to the next. Building upon this foundation, Section 3 provides an overview of the model structure and its integration within a broader suite of evolving models. Moving forward, Section 4 presents a comprehensive analysis of the dynamic and empirical properties of PAMPh2.0, employing various analytical tools such as impulse response analysis, historical simulations, and an assessment of in-sample forecasting performance. This section also underscores the role of calibration and estimation methods. Lastly, Section 5 encapsulates the primary findings, challenges, and outlines the steps for future advancements.

Multi-Phase Technical Assistance Proceedings

The modernization of the BSP’s Policy Analysis Model for the Philippines (PAMPh) is a multi-year collaboration between the IMF Institute for Capacity Development (ICD) and the BSP Department of Economic Research (DER). Phase 1 of the Technical Assistance (TA) started with first on-site mission in April 2022 aimed to build upon the initial version of PAMPh, focusing on reviewing its features and forecasting performance.

The second phase of the mission, conducted in October 2022, detailed decomposition of aggregate demand, external, and fiscal sectors was introduced, enabling quantification of the model’s transmission channels and interlinkages of its different policy instruments to effectively communicate different policy trade-offs. This phase concluded with a meeting discussing challenges, risks, and opportunities with the Governor and members of the Monetary Board to strengthen the BSP’s policy frameworks.

The subsequent TA mission in March 2023 focused on further enhancing PAMPh’s calibration and storytelling capacity. The mission also introduced further extension to the model by developing a systematic assessment of its forecasting performance. Initial discussions commenced on institutional changes necessary for PAMPh’s planned adoption as the BSP’s workhorse model for monetary policy analysis and forecasting.

In July 2023, the fourth phase of the TA incorporated credit cycle dynamics in the Philippines, focusing on macrofinancial linkages and the role of macroprudential policy in achieving economic and financial stability. Capital flow management measures were also added to the model during this phase, analyzing its impact on exchange rate dynamics and monetary conditions, and interactions with other policies. The mission concluded with discussions on future steps for PAMPh with senior management.

In February and March 2024, the TA mission completed phase five by extending the PAMPh model to incorporate the labor block. During this phase, the DER-EFFG and ICD TA team addressed BSP senior management’s concerns regarding model structure, market interest rate, policy rule calibration to align with senior management’s preferences, supply shock treatment, and inflation expectations. The mission concluded with a presentation led by DER-EFFG to the BSP Monetary Board and Advisory Committee on Monetary Policy, covering model issues raised by senior management, PAMPh-based shadow forecasts, and assessment of alternative scenarios.

2. Stylized Facts from the Philippines and Model Motivation

To ensure its relevance in macroeconomic policy analysis and monetary policy formulation, PAMPh2.0 incorporates the crucial stylized facts of the Philippine economy, closely aligning with the BSP’s policy framework. Acknowledging the policy significance of integrating country-specific features into the analytical framework, this section outlines the stylized facts of the Philippines that drive specific deviations from a standard QPM and the need to complement traditional policies with non-traditional ones. These adaptations aim to enhance the model’s structure and properties, with detailed explanations provided in Sections 3 and 4.

  • 2.1 GDP and Expenditure Side Decomposition

Over the past two decades, the Philippine economy has grown at an average of 5.0 percent from 2001 to 2023. It experienced accelerated economic growth in the mid-2000s, propelled by robust domestic demand ( Figure 2.1 ) and favorable global conditions. The global financial crisis (GFC) in 2008–2009 led to temporary setbacks, with GDP growth slowing to 1.4 percent in 2009. Following the GFC, GDP rebounded strongly, growing at 6.4 percent from 2010 to 2019, with over 6.0 percent growth sustained for eight consecutive years starting in 2012. Private consumption, investment, and public consumption all made steady contributions to growth. The resilient services and industry sectors ( Figure 2.2 ) played a significant role, accounting for approximately 90 percent of the economy’s performance. The output gap was generally positive during this period particularly in 2018–2019 ( Figure 2.3 ). Growth was later interrupted by the significant contraction in 2020 due to the COVID-19 pandemic.

From 2021 to 2022, a calibrated reopening of the economy, coupled with a favorable global economic landscape, government policy support, and structural reforms, spurred a strong recovery in the Philippines. The services sector emerged as the primary driver of this recovery on the supply side, benefitting from relaxed mobility restrictions, the resumption of face-to-face classes, and eased travel protocols. On the demand side, growth was observed in household and government expenditures, as well as in investments, fueled by increased mobility of people, goods, and services due to further relaxation of COVID-related quarantine measures, sustaining economic growth.

Contribution to growth, expenditure side

Citation: IMF Working Papers 2024, 148; 10.5089/9798400284298.001.A001

  • Download Figure
  • Download figure as PowerPoint slide

Contribution to growth, production side

  • 2.2 Labor Market and Wage Developments

Before the COVID-19 pandemic, the Philippines witnessed its longest economic and job growth period. Not only did employment numbers rise significantly, but job quality, measured by the increase in wage and salary workers, also showed a steady annual growth rate of 4.6 percent from 2015 to 2019 ( Figures 2.4 and 2.5 ). However, the pandemic reversed these gains, leading to the loss of 1.7 million wage and salary jobs by January 2021. With the easing of quarantine measures, labor market gradually improved in 2022, with unemployment rates dropping to their lowest point since the peak of the pandemic.

Nevertheless, labor quality was late to improve as sustained growth in wage and salary workers only became evident beginning in 2023. In the interim, average daily pay 6 has kept pace with the daily minimum wage, with both measures experiencing an average growth rate of 4.5 percent from 2005 to 2012. However, since 2013, the growth of average daily pay has accelerated to 5.4 percent, while the growth in minimum wage has slowed down to 3.0 percent. Adjusting for inflation, average daily pay grew marginally by 0.2 percent in 2023, significantly lower than its 10-year average of 1.9 percent. Meanwhile, real minimum wage increased by 1.3 percent last year, significantly higher than its 10-year average growth of -0.2 percent, reflecting the series of wage increases over the past year which aims to restore purchasing power among the minimum wage earners ( Figure 2.6 ).

This analysis is supplemented by the Labor Utilization Composite Index (LUCI), which offers an overview of the labor market situation in the Philippines ( Figure 2.7 ). It combines data from nine labor market variables 7 using the principal components method. LUCI estimates indicate a significant loosening of the labor market in 2020–2021, but gradual improvement has been observed since Q1 2022. Estimates for Q4 2023 show sustained enhancement in the LUCI, signaling a positive shift in the current labor market conditions, which may potentially lead to inflationary pressures in the upcoming quarters.

Employment indicators

Employment by class of workers

Real daily wages

Labor utilization composite index

  • 2.3 Prices: Core and Non-Core Subcomponents

In the initial years since the adoption of the IT framework from 2002 to 2009, headline inflation settled above the target range in four out of eight years, below the target range for three years and within the target range once ( Figure 2.8 ). Periods of below-target inflation were usually driven by easing global and domestic food and oil prices. Meanwhile, periods of above-target inflation were affected by supply-side shocks from higher global oil prices and second-round effect on transport fares, adverse impact of weather conditions such as El NiĂąo on domestic food production, and implementation of higher value-added tax (VAT) and excise taxes. 8

The period after the GFC was characterized by low and stable inflation and strong domestic economic activity. GDP growth expanded above the historical trend at 6.5 percent from 2010 to 2017. Nonetheless, implementation of government structural reforms, together with enhancements in the BSP’s monetary policy framework, helped bring inflation slightly below 3.0 percent.

Guo et al., (2019) reported a significant inflation spike in 2018 attributed to various supply-side factors, including surges in global crude oil prices, increased domestic excise taxes on oil and “sin” items, and elevated domestic rice prices due to restricted import quotas. Concurrently, demand-side pressures were evident with the rise in services inflation, coinciding with the slightly positive output gap estimated for the period leading to 2018.

In the subsequent years (2019–2020), headline and core inflation decelerated, returning to within the target range, primarily due to lower food and energy prices. Food inflation moderated as supply conditions improved, aided by structural reforms like the implementation of the Rice Tariffication Law (RTL), which led to decreased rice prices. Additionally, the easing of energy prices in 2019 and at the onset of the pandemic in 2020 contributed to maintaining inflation within the target range.

Consumer price inflation

In 2021, headline inflation began to rise, driven by increased food and energy inflation ( Figure 2.9 ). Food inflation was primarily fueled by domestic supply constraints on key food items such as meat, exacerbated by the African Swine Fever outbreak and adverse weather conditions affecting fish production. Energy inflation escalated as the global economy gradually re-opened from pandemic-induced lockdowns. Concurrently, core inflation slowed down due to the lingering effects of the pandemic on the output gap, leading to deceleration in both core goods and services inflation ( Figure 2.10 ).

In 2022 and 2023, inflation surged, averaging 5.8 percent and 6.0 percent, respectively, driven by consecutive supply-side shocks and ensuing second-round effects. Escalating oil and fertilizer prices, stemming from the Russia and Ukraine conflict, significantly raised domestic energy costs. Persistent weather disruptions affecting key food supplies also contributed to inflation pressures. Additionally, second-round effects, including transport fare hikes, electricity adjustments, and higher minimum wages, fueled core inflation in both years.

The trends in relative prices indicated that the surge in energy prices in 2021 followed by the early-2022 war shock contributed to inflationary pressures ( Figure 2.11 ). Furthermore, positive second-round effects were evident in the second half of 2022, as the relative price of core became elevated compared to the levels from previous years.

Contribution to inflation

Core, goods, and services inflation

Relative prices

  • 2.4 Banking Sector and Credit Cycle

The Philippine banking sector remains the primary driver of the financial system, with banks accounting for approximately 78 percent of total financial assets from 2010 to 2023, ( Figure 2.12 ). In 2023, Philippine banks sustained strong performance, supported by robust capital and liquidity buffers alongside continuous growth in assets, loans, deposits, and profits. They have maintained capital and liquidity buffers exceeding both the BSP and international standards. As of end-June 2023, solo and consolidated capital adequacy ratios (CARs) for Universal and Commercials Banks (U/KBs) stood at 16.3 percent and 16.9 percent, respectively, significantly surpassing the BSP’s minimum requirement of 10 percent and the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) standard of 8.0 percent ( Figure 2.13 ).

Total assets of the PHL banking system

Capital adequacy ratio

Despite the pandemic’s challenges and BSP policy rate increases to curb inflation, Philippine banks adeptly facilitated funds by seamlessly offering financial products and services to households and businesses. Outstanding credit relative to nominal GDP, has risen steadily since 2010 onwards, averaging 44 percent from 2010 to 2023, underscoring the Philippines’ growing economic demands ( Figure 2.14 ). By 2023, the credit-to-GDP ratio surged to 54 percent, reflecting robust economic recovery post-pandemic, with production loans comprising over 90 percent of total credit ( Figure 2.15 ) and increasing financial intermediation reflected in the increasing trend of credit on GDP. Concurrently, real estate credit share climbed from 13 percent in 2010 to 20 percent in 2023, mirroring sustained growth in construction and the real estate sector. A positive credit gap ( Figure 2.16 ) has started to open in 2018 owing to rising credit growth in support of the expansion needs of the economy. Nonetheless, tighter financial conditions 9 ( Figure 2.17 ), given the BSP’s significant monetary policy tightening, exchange rate pressures, and rising property prices have helped reduce the credit gap. The credit gap in the end of 2023 has turned slightly negative.

Outstanding loans (% of GDP)

Production loans by main sector

Financial conditions index

The average bank lending rate 10 ( Figure 2.18 ) has generally tracked the BSP policy rate. The positive spread reflects both term premium, a product of maturity transformation, and credit risk. The positive spread between the two rates widened considerably during the pandemic when economic sentiments were negative and risk perception was heightened. Results of the BSP Senior Bank Loan Officers’ Survey showed net tightening of overall credit standards for both loans to enterprises and households during the COVID-19 pandemic.

Reflecting the banking sector’s pivotal role in financial intermediation and the economy’s dependence on it due to the nascent domestic capital markets, loans have consistently dominated banks’ balance sheets ( Figure 2.19 ). Increasing from 63 percent in 2010 to around 73 percent in 2023, loans remained as significant portion of U/KB’s total assets. Meanwhile, the capital-to-asset ratio (leverage ratio) has maintained stability at approximately 12 percent, apart from a temporary surge in Q1 2013 attributed to a notable uptick in bank capital ( Figure 2.20 ).

Interest rates

Composition of assets of U/KBs

The capital of Philippine banks has, in turn, been supported by profitable operations and high-quality assets. After dipping slightly during the pandemic reflecting the contraction in economic activity, return on assets (ROA) has improved with the calibrated reopening of the domestic economy and phased removal of regulatory relief measures that allowed banks to resume normal banking operations. As of Q4 2023, ROA of U/KBs ( Figure 2.21 ) has risen to 1.5 percent from 0.8 percent at the height (Q1 2021) of the pandemic, while the share of non-performing loans to total assets fell to 1.6 percent from 2.1 percent during the same period.

Leverage ratio

ROA and NPL ratio

BSP macroprudential measures are in place but remain limited. The framework that sets up the countercyclical capital buffer (CCyB) implementation for U/KBs and subsidiary banks was announced in December 2018 (BSP Circular No. 1024). Nonetheless, the mechanism to operationalize the CCyB, including the decision-making framework, is not yet active. Philippine banks are currently subject to a CCyB of 0.0 percent with upward adjustment in CCyB to be determined by the Monetary Board when systemic conditions warrant. Any increase in the CCyB rate will be effective 12 months after its announcement but decreases will be implemented immediately. In addition, the BSP has pre-deployed macroprudential measures that can be adjusted in a countercyclical manner to prevent financial imbalances. Examples of these include caps on loan-to-value ratios, general loan loss provisioning, single borrower limits, concentration limits, limits on open FX positions, asset cover for banks’ foreign currency deposit unit (FCDU) liabilities, and liquidity measures.

  • 2.5 Monetary Policy and Transmission Mechanism

The BSP has adopted a flexible inflation targeting (FIT) framework in conducting monetary policy. Its primary instrument is the overnight reverse repurchase (RRP) rate, which the BSP adjusts based on the emerging outlook for inflation, GDP growth, and other macroeconomic variables (e.g., interest rates, exchange rate, domestic credit and equity prices, indicators of demand and supply, and external economic conditions).

The BSP has been operating a symmetric interest rate corridor (IRC) since June 2016, with the deposit and lending facility rates set 50 basis points (bps) below and above the target RRP rate. As the BSP adjusts the target RRP rate based on its outlook for inflation and business cycle, the interest rates for the overnight deposit and lending facilities are correspondingly set. The BSP also operates active term liquidity facilities to help absorb structural excess liquidity from the financial system in aid of monetary transmission. These include the auctions for 7- and 14-day term deposit facilities, and the 28- and 56-day BSP Securities. The BSP can likewise adjust the reserve requirements, which currently stands at 9.5 percent for U/KBs from its double-digit level in the past decade, and the rediscount rate on loans extended by the BSP to banking institutions. The BSP can also undertake outright sales or purchases of government securities to adjust the liquidity in the financial system.

The passthrough of policy rate adjustments to overnight market rates is generally high. Both the IBCL and overnight PHIREF rates broadly track the movements of the RRP rate. Post adoption of the IRC system in 2016, a correlation coefficient of 0.99 between the RRP and IBCL rates was observed. The correlation for PHIREF was slightly lower at 0.92. On average, both rates fall below the RRP rate but the IBCL rate has a smaller spread against the RRP rate. Traditionally, the BSP has utilized the unsecured IBCL rate, along with other market interest rates, as its primary indicator to guide open market operations. However, following the implementation of variable-rate RRP auctions in September 2023, the BSP looks at the overnight RRP rate as its principal market rate.

The real interest rate remained negative for much of 2020–2022 due to policy rate cuts amid the COVID-19 pandemic. However, it has since trended higher reaching 3.7 percent in Q1 2024, following the 450-bp increase in the RRP rate by the BSP to address significant inflation pressure.

While the passthrough of policy rate adjustments to short-term market rates appear to be high, the passthrough for interest rates at the longer horizon could be moderated. For instance, the interest rate for long-term bank loans may be influenced by perception of risks on economic prospects and inflation as well as credit worthiness of borrower. 11

O/N PHIREF, IBCL, RRP, ODF, and OLF rates

Real interest rate and real effective exchange rate

  • 2.6 Fiscal Policy and Public Finances

Since the onset of the COVID-19 pandemic in 2020, the fiscal balance has widened as the government pursued fiscal accommodation to support the economy amidst the global health crisis. Transitioning from an average of 2.9 percent from 2017 to 2019, the fiscal deficit to GDP ratio more than doubled to 7.9 percent from 2020 to 2022 ( Figure 2.24 ). In 2020, total government revenues contracted by 9.0 percent due to reduced business operations amid necessary mobility restrictions aimed at curbing the spread of the virus. However, revenues rebounded by 18.0 percent in 2022, propelled by higher tax collection, as pent-up demand drove increased economic activity. To address the pandemic and its containment measures, the government enacted Bayanihan 1 12 and Bayanihan 2 13 in 2020 to implement emergency health and social protection programs. 14 Additionally, the notable increase in government spending in 2018 was fueled by growth in infrastructure and other capital expenditures.

NG fiscal performance

NG outstanding debt (% of GDP)

The country’s larger financing requirements coupled with weaker domestic output growth, led to increased debt levels. Prior to the pandemic, the government debt-to-GDP ratio remained stable at about 40 percent, reflecting prudent debt management and robust economic growth ( Figure 2.25 ). However, total outstanding debt rose in 2020, reaching 61 percent of GDP by the end of 2022, with the national government (NG) favoring domestic borrowing to manage foreign exchange risks.

In pursuit of short-term macro-fiscal stability and medium-term fiscal sustainability, the government adopted the 2022–2028 Medium-Term Fiscal Framework (MTFF) in 2022. Through this framework, originally the government announced its medium-term goals, aiming to reduce the fiscal deficit to 3.0 percent of GDP by 2028 and the NG debt to less than 60 percent of GDP by 2025. 15 To achieve these targets, the government plans to increase revenues through existing tax measures such as the Sin Tax Law and the Tax Reform for Acceleration and Inclusion (TRAIN), along with proposed priority tax measures, and enhanced tax administration efficiency through digitalization. In addition to the priority tax measures outlined in the MTFF, such as imposing value-added tax on digital service providers and excise tax on single-use plastics, the government is also seeking to improve the fiscal regime for the mining industry and implement a motor vehicle road user’s tax, among other initiatives. On the expenditure side, the government aims to modernize the budgeting system through the Progressive Budgeting for Better and Modernized Government Bill, streamline NG agencies with the National Government Rightsizing Program, and mitigate fiscal risks related to military and uniformed personnel pensions.

  • 2.7 External Balance

The Philippines experienced large fluctuations in its current account balance over the past decade. Initially in surplus and averaging 3.0 percent of GDP from 2011 to 2015, the current account shifted to a deficit from 2016 to 2019, averaging -1.1 percent of GDP, before returning to a large surplus in 2020 at 3.2 percent of GDP ( Figure 2.26 ). These fluctuations were driven mainly by widening and narrowing trade deficits in goods while balances in other accounts such as services, primary, and secondary income remained stable. Furthermore, substantial current account deficits emerged in 2021–2022, subsequently narrowing in 2023. This trend was driven by the reduction in the deficit for goods, offset by the uptick in service imports fueled by pent-up demand for travel. Both primary and secondary income accounts have made favorable contributions to the current account balance.

The Philippines consistently maintained robust foreign reserves to finance this deficit. From 2004 to 2011, reserves increased from 106 percent to a peak of 273 percent of the IMF’s ARA metric. By the end of 2023, gross international reserves (GIR) had reached US$102.5 billion, up from US$44.2 billion in 2009 ( Figure 2.27 ) following the GFC. This increase was driven by increased dollar inflows due to the US Fed’s quantitative easing and ultra-low interest rate policy. Similarly, GIR surged in 2020 due to increased foreign loans by the NG in response to the COVID-19 pandemic and funding for the country’s infrastructure program. The steady flow of dollar remittances from overseas Filipino workers (OFW) and receipts from business process outsourcing (BPO) firms have also contributed to the growth of foreign reserves.

Total capital flows grew more moderately, averaging 3.6 percent of GDP in the 2000s to 5.4 percent of GDP in the 2010s. This increase was partly due to the low interest rate regime in advanced economies post-GFC, leading to a search for yield in EME bond markets ( Figure 2.28 ). Additionally, the BSP’s foreign exchange liberalization reforms since 2007 and changes in foreign bank entry regulations in 2014 also contributed to the rise in capital flows. Despite these reforms, the Philippines still maintains substantial capital flow restrictions, as indicated by the Fernandez, et al. (2016) index, which classifies the Philippines as a “wall” country, with controls in over 70 percent of cross-border transactions ( Figure 2.29 ) ( IMF 2022 ). Similarly, the Chinn-Ito index (Chinn, et al. (2006) ) indicates a low degree of capital account openness for the Philippines, reflecting significant barriers to capital movements across borders.

Current account balance

Gross international reserves

Total capital flows

Financial openness

The Philippine Emerging Markets Bond Index (EMBI) spread, a key metric of country risk premium, currently sits around 300 bps ( Figure 2.30 ). This reflects significant improvement compared to peaks of 724 bps and 577 bps during the GFC and the COVID-19 pandemic, respectively. The relative stability in the EMBI spread in recent years indicated the Philippines’ enhanced resilience against external economic shocks. This resilience can be attributed to sustained economic growth and sound macroeconomic fundamentals, bolstered further by successive credit rating upgrades in the early-2010s.

Meanwhile, the peso-dollar rate depreciated from 2013 to 2018, coinciding with the US Federal Reserve tapering its asset purchases, which triggered liquidity concerns globally and heightened risk perception. Consequently, emerging market currencies, including the Philippine peso, weakened as investors sought safer destinations for their funds. From 2019 through 2021, the peso appreciated against the dollar on the back of low and stable inflation, strong and resilient banking system, and high level of international reserves. The current account surplus during the pandemic likewise supported the strength of the peso. As the global economy reopened and faced the headwinds of higher commodity prices due to geopolitical tensions in 2022, several advanced economies have begun aggressive monetary policy tightening. This has resulted in renewed depreciation of the peso to its current level.

EMBI spread and exchange rate

  • 2.8 Foreign Trade

The Philippines has experienced a trade deficit for most years, as imports of capital goods, consumer goods, and raw materials surpassed the value of key exports such as electronic products, machinery, textiles, and agricultural products. The country’s major trading partners included the United States, China, Japan, South Korea, and ASEAN member countries. Key exports included electronics, semiconductors, clothing, machinery and equipment, coconut oil, and tropical fruits. Imports consisted primarily of intermediate goods and capital equipment essential for domestic production and infrastructure development, crucial for sustaining economic growth. Additionally, the external sector benefited from remittances from the OFWs and receipts from tourism and BPO industry.

External Assumptions . The external block of the PAMPh is determined by forecasts from the Global Projections Model Network (GPMN), which uses the GPM++ Model. This model, originating from the IMF’s Global Projection Model, covers approximately 30 countries, representing around 80 percent of the world GDP. It encompasses commodities and financial linkages to the real economy. 16 Global macroeconomic variables adopted exogenously by the PAMPh include output gap and CPI changes in key regions, namely the US, Euro Zone, China, Japan, and others. Price changes of oil and food in the international market that impact domestic food and energy inflation directly, are sourced from GPM++ projections. Estimated spillovers and exchange rate changes from these regions, along with the impact of interest rate movements from major central banks like the US Federal Reserve, are also incorporated into PAMPh.

3. A Modern Policy Analysis Model for the Philippines (PAMPh2.0)

The economic considerations and transmission mechanisms detailed earlier are integrated into the PAMPh structure, making it a relevant and effective tool for real-time policy analysis and forecasting. Inspired by FINEX, PAMPh2.0 emphasizes external and internal balances by explicitly incorporating macroeconomic and financial blocks, reaction functions and rules. This integration establishes a comprehensive policy framework with diverse instruments, significantly enhancing the depth of policy analysis. Specifically, the framework provides a systematic and practical method for structured forecasting and policy analysis, integrating traditional monetary and fiscal policies with non-traditional tools such as FXI, CFMs, and MPMs, and assessing their interaction in response to economic shocks. Moreover, PAMPh2.0-based analysis of fiscal-monetary-macrofinancial interactions takes into account crucial factors like initial debt levels and the sensitivity of inflation to exchange rate depreciation, among others.

PAMPh2.0 incorporates insights from recent DSGE literature while maintaining a gap-trend structure conducive to practical policy applications, emphasizing a “positive” policy analysis approach. This framework is designed to facilitate the interpretation of recent data in terms of structural shocks and policy responses, aiding policymakers in constructing internally-consistent medium-term baseline projections, economic narratives, and conducting alternative scenarios. Appendix [D] offers an overview of the practical utilization of structural and semi-structural models within policy institutions, emphasizing the roles of PAMPh2.0 and other DSGE-based policy models such as the quantitative model for the Integrated Policy Framework (QIPF). 17

Macroeconomic dynamics in PAMPh2.0 depend on the interplay of internal balance, external balance, and policy. Internal balance is woven into the determination of both output and inflation. This relationship is elucidated through the interaction of demand and supply, represented by an extended IS curve and a corresponding set of Phillips curves. Moving to external balance , the exchange rate plays a pivotal role in reconciling the balance of payments (BoP), thereby exerting influence on net exports and other components within the BoP framework. The dynamics of financial flows are contingent upon the difference between domestic and foreign interest rates, adjusted for anticipated depreciation, thereby deviating from the Uncovered Interest Parity (UIP). This straightforward formulation encapsulates the implications of external shocks and policies, including FXI, which significantly impacts the necessity for portfolio capital flows to maintain equilibrium within the BoP. CFMs further play a distinctive role, influencing the effective interest rate for foreign investors, shaping the stock of Net Foreign Assets (NFA), and thereby shaping the economy’s response to external shocks. As for policy , the levers of monetary policy, fiscal policy (encompassing government absorption through consumption and investment, along with tax considerations), FXI, MPMs, and CFMs 18 are inherently linked to variables such as inflation, output, debt, exchange rate, and other specified objectives. Additionally, there is an increased emphasis on labor market policies to provide deeper insights into the analysis of labor market dynamics and their implications for inflation forecasts. 19

It is essential to acknowledge from the outset that within the framework of PAMPh2.0, as demonstrated in the subsequent risk scenario analyses and policy simulations, the policy reaction parameters are not optimized but rather calibrated (discussed further in Section 4.2). While it is conceivable to optimize the reaction functions based on a loss function, the resulting outcomes would inherently depend on several factors, including the calibration of the economy, the distribution of shocks, and the characteristics of the policy regime. For instance, the extent of the interest rate reaction to inflation would be influenced by the strength of the FXI response to changes in the exchange rate. Policymakers are aware that models only approximate reality in many cases, thus they often prioritize flexibility in reflecting their own preferred reaction functions. Nevertheless, they still rely on the resulting model forecasts as a crucial tool to assess the policy stance.

The main structural assumptions and channels in PAMPh2.0 are depicted in Figure 3.1 .

PAMPh2.0 – Diagram of Key Relations and Channels

In Figure 3.1 , we underscore certain aspects of internal and external balances . The output gap serves as a metric for the cyclical positioning of GDP, shedding light on distinct contributions from consumption, investment, and net exports. Household private consumption and investment activities are influenced by monetary conditions (real interest rate and lending conditions) and are impacted by the income channel. Export levels hinge on foreign demand and competitiveness (assessed through the real exchange rate and real export prices) while imports are propelled by domestic demand and an expenditure-switching mechanism. Real exchange rate depreciation prompts a reduction in the demand for foreign goods, thereby enhancing the net export position. Inflationary pressures emanate from the output gap, imported inflation, and the effects of commodity prices.

Shifting the focus to policies , they play a fundamentally stabilizing role, with monetary policy adhering to the Taylor principle and fiscal policy aimed at stabilizing the debt-GDP ratio. 20

Regarding monetary policy, the BSP employs three tools to fulfill its mandate of maintaining price stability and supporting real economic activity:

Regarding fiscal policy, PAMPh2.0 features a simple, parsimonious model using a reaction function in which fiscal authorities aim to maintain public debt at a targeted level and stabilize economic activity by keeping economic growth close to its potential level. The reaction function guides fiscal policy decisions: the government decides on the level of the cyclically-adjusted primary balance based on factors such as the deviation of public debt from the targeted level and the cyclical position of the economy. Government instruments—multiple sources of revenues and current and capital spending (including social transfers) are adjusted to achieve the fiscal balance target. Tax-based vs. expenditure-based fiscal consolidation is highlighted in the policy section below with a greater need for coordination between monetary and fiscal policy. Further, the government’s reaction to economic conditions through fiscal policy decisions feeds back into real economic activity. The fiscal impulse (the change in fiscal policy stance) has an impact on economic activity and fiscal policy decisions also influence inflation (through a second-round inflationary effect, which is limited). The detailed exposition of the BoP and external financing in PAMPh2.0 incorporates crucial and innovative elements derived from Berg et al. (2023 ). The net export position serves as the linchpin for the underlying dynamics of the current account, influenced further by additional foreign-related income, interest income and foreign direct investment return. The financial account, mirroring the current account, dictates the external financing position of the economy. The country risk premium, contingent on external financing, shapes the dynamics of the nominal exchange rate, thereby influencing inflation pressures. PAMPh2.0 is also equipped to examine scenarios where policymakers implement CFMs to restrict the private sector’s access to foreign financing, subsequently addressing the adverse effects of capital outflows or DMCs.

Finally, Figure 3.1 depicts a banking sector with credit channels, inspired by QPM-style models. This addition enriches the model and facilitates specific credit and asset price channels and interactions. Within this framework, commercial banks extend consumer credit to households and collateralized credit to firms for housing. The lending rates are tied to compounded effective market rates (which will be discussed below), closely connected to the monetary policy rate. Additionally, asset prices, intimately associated with real economic activity, dynamically influence the collateral credit position, introducing endogenous financial cycles within the model.

Most of the model equations are linear . However, nonlinearity has also been incorporated. This is the case in the macroprudential block, for example, when U/KBs first reduce dividend payments built-up capital. Only when it is not sufficient, banks raise spreads. Similar nonlinear effects are used in the case of public debt or limits on FXI when reserves get too low.

Before we dive into the model structure and relationships, let’s introduce some notation. All variables are expressed in log variables and decomposed into gap and trend components. The gaps, percentage deviation from the potential or trend level, are described by detailed structural equations associated with the macroeconomic theory. We denoted the gaps by hat over the variable ( ︷ ) , e.g., the output gap is written as ŷ . The trends are described with relatively simple autoregressive processes and are assigned by bar ( ¯ ) , e.g., the potential GDP is denoted by y ¯ . The structural equations for the fiscal and external balance contain variables in terms of nominal GDP (or we also refer to the variables expressed in terms of nominal GDP as great ratios); for these variables, we add a superscript ( ) rat , e.g., debt rat denotes the public debt to GDP ratio.

We will now elaborate on each internal and external balance and policy sequentially.

  • 3.1 Internal Balance

3.1.1 Real Economy and Aggregate Demand

PAMPh2.0 follows in large part the advances made by Berg et al. (2023 ) in terms of QPM development. GDP (Y) on the expenditure side is decomposed into private consumption (C), gross capital accumulation (Inv) , government consumption (Gc) , export (X) and import (M). Corresponding price deflators for each GDP component are modeled, denoted by P with the superscripts referring to the different GDP components.

Most of the model equations including the GDP-identity are expressed in a linearized version. The GDP (output) gap ( y ^ ) is computed as the weighted average of the expenditure-side components, with the time-variant weights derived from the nominal GDP ratios in relation to potential levels:

Eq.1 is also applicable to trend variables. The GDP trend can be represented as the weighted average of the growth rates of each expenditure-side component, with weights determined by the nominal GDP ratios, as follows:

Cyclical position of GDP expenditure side components

First, we outline the gap equations, illustrating the key characteristics of New Keynesian theory. Each equation can be associated with a reduced linearized equation in DSGE models.

The consumption gap adheres to the fundamental properties of the Euler equation observed in applied DSGE models with external habit formation (Smets and Wouters, (2007)). It is a function of both backward and forward-looking expectations, monetary conditions, and the disposable income position:

where consumption gap, denoted by ( c ^ ) , is influenced by various factors. The real interest rate gap ( r ^ ) , encompassing the real loan rate gap ( r ^ L ) , and the risk premium gap ( p r e m ^ ) , constitutes the monetary conditions. Tight monetary conditions, resulting from restrictive monetary policy or tight lending conditions set by commercial banks, lead to a lower consumption gap. The income component comprises the output gap ( y ^ ) , terms-of-trade from export ( r p ^ x ) and import ( r p ^ m ) relative price gaps 21 , remittances ( r e m Κ t ^ r a t ) , wages paid will be approximated by a real wage gap ( w r ^ , defined below) adjusted by the relative price difference between the core prices ( r p ^ c o r e ) and consumption deflators ( r p ^ c ) , and taxes paid as a source of revenue to the government ( r e v ^ ) . The consumption equation contains two shocks, ξ c ^ denotes the preference shocks that increase the idiosyncratic changes of the consumption gap, while ξ n c r ^ h , r a t is the shock to household credit implying that access to a better credit position also results in higher consumption. The income channel plays a prominent role in capturing the second-round effects of labor, capital and dividend income from firms and the effect of fiscal redistribution policies. The relative price gaps illustrate the potential impact of the foreign trading sector: the increasing profitability of Philippine exporters is reflected in the rising real price of exports, while the potential worsening terms-of-trade, with adverse effects on consumption, is captured through the real import price gap. 22 Through the expectation channel, past or future expected monetary and income conditions also play a role in determining the consumption gap.

Labor and wages

First, to provide additional insights into labor and wages in PAMPh2.0, two additional equations—a wage Phillips curve and an unemployment rate equation—are discussed below. The structure and calibration of these equations are motivated by a DSGE framework.

Business Wage Phillips Curve . Its derivation follows the approach outlined by Erceg et al. (2000), with the following shape:

Δw B is nominal business wage q-o-q growth determined by the business cycle conditions, E t Δ w t + 1 B is the expected nominal wage growth in time t+1 based on information in time t, c ^ is the consumption gap, w r ^ is the real wage gap, and ε Δw M is the spillover effect of the minimum wage increase on business wages. Eq.5 assumes wage growth is driven by expected and actual past wage growth. It is affected by the consumption gap and the real wage gap capturing deviations of the real wage from the marginal rate of substitution between leisure and work—a positive consumption gap also implies high production and thus higher demand for labor, resulting in wage growth pressures; and a negative real wage gap means that labor is relatively cheaper compared to other production factors, raising demand for labor and nominal wage growth.

A set of additional equations accompanies (eq.5). First, a significant part of the labor force receives a minimum wage set by the government exogenously:

where the w M denotes the minimum wage. The total wage index is given as the weighted average of minimum and business wages:

The identity defining the real wage (wr) is:

where w is a natural log of nominal wage and cpi is a natural log of consumer price index derived below from price Phillips curves. 23 The real wage is decomposed into a gap, denoted as w r ^ , and a trend denoted as, w r ÂŻ :

The trend real wage w r ÂŻ is assumed to follow an autoregressive process, where the faster-than-steady-state potential growth rate exerts additional growth on the real wage trend:

where Δwr ss denotes the steady-state real wage trend growth, Δ y ¯ and Δy ss are the trend (potential) real GDP growth and the steady-state real GDP growth, respectively, and ε Δ w r ¯ is a shock.

Unemployment rate . The Okun’s law equation links the unemployment rate gap, denoted as u n e ^ , with real economic activity:

It assumes that the labor market operates according to the real business cycle with a lag, as reflected in the persistence of the unemployment gap and the inclusion of the lagged value of the output gap. The unemployment gap along with the trend in the unemployment rate – the NAIRU or non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment, u n e ¯ , provides the unemployment rate, une:

The NAIRU is determined by the structural characteristics of the labor market and influenced by potential GDP growth:

The equation assumes that in the steady state, the level of the unemployment rate is determined by the structural characteristics determining u n e ÂŻ s s . This structural level is adjusted by deviations of potential GDP growth from its long-term level. Faster potential GDP growth reduces the NAIRU, while slower growth increases it.

Moving on to other aggregate demand components, the investment gap ( Κ n v ^ ) is guided by the Tobin-Q portfolio theory ( Tobin and Brainard (1977) ). The Tobin-Q ( q ^ ) serves as a measure of the market value of the capital stock, providing insights into the incentives for capital investment. When q ^ surpasses the relative price of the actual investment, or the relative price of investment, firms tend to increase their investment in the economy. The investment equation is expressed as follows:

Here Tobin-Q is defined as the present value of the next period’s output level and the future value of portfolio investment:

The expected value of the output gap serves as a proxy for the yields on capital. A combination of the real interest rate gap, the real lending rate gap, and the risk premium is employed as an effective measure for monetary conditions to discount the expected market value of future investments. Additionally, in eq.15, the investment equation incorporates public capital expenditures ( e x ^ i , r a t ) as a substantial component of gross capital accumulation in the Philippines, driven by public capital expenditures and infrastructure projects. The shock to firms’ new credit ( ε n c r ^ f , r a t ) contributes to the investment positively. The shock term ( ε ι n v ^ ) accounts for the unmodelled part of investment activity, representing a temporary shock. Notably, in emerging economies, investment volatility is significantly larger than in advanced economies ( Aguiar and Gopinath (2007) ). The government consumption 24 is assumed to be exogenous, and the gap equation follows an autoregressive process:

In relation to foreign trade, the export gap ( x ^ ) follows an autoregressive process, incorporating a fundamental component tied to foreign demand ( y ^ w ) and the difference between the real effective exchange rate gap ( r e e r ^ ) and the real price of export ( r p ^ X )

The export gap equation is derived from the neoclassical production function, incorporating key features of open economy models. The demand for exports depends on foreign output. Furthermore, export sensitivity is also affected by relative price differentials (a 25 ). However, the elasticity is relatively lower due to the significant contribution of a semiconductor sector. Consequently, a depreciating real exchange rate (i.e., improvement of competitiveness) does not stimulate exports as much as in other open economies with a more diversified export industry.

The import gap (to capture cyclical import dynamics) is expressed as follows:

Under a small open economy and a relatively high share of foreign goods in final consumption, the import gap depends on the expenditure gaps of consumption ( c ^ ) , investment ( Κ n v ^ ) , government absorption ( g c ^ ) , and exports ( x ^ ) . We assume that in the case of imported consumption, the household can substitute foreign goods with domestic ones (through the expenditure switching channel). Therefore, the consumption gap is adjusted by the real exchange rate gap ( r e e r ^ ) . With real exchange rate depreciation, households decrease their import, generating more demand for domestic goods, and the improvement in net exports increases the output gap. However, the effectiveness of this expenditure switching is limited (the coefficient a 31 is relatively small). Furthermore, for other imported final goods such as government consumption, exports, or investment, there is no expenditure switching, as these goods are assumed to be sector-specific and are imported from trading partners not available in the domestic economy. 25

The autoregressive term captures adjustment costs that result in a gradual accommodation in import demand. However, due to large, mostly idiosyncratic shocks beyond demand factors, there are unexplained temporary components in imports. The coefficients a 30 ,a 32 and a 33 are calibrated based on the input-output (I/O) tables, as discussed in the Calibration section below. These coefficients capture the consistent flow of goods and services in accordance with the System of National Accounts (SNA). 26

Trends of the GDP expenditure side components

The trend equations align with the FINEX model ( Berg et al., 2023 ), establishing trends to uphold constant nominal GDP ratios along the steady-state balanced growth path. Consequently, these trends impose constraints on real growth values. Additionally, error correction terms are incorporated to facilitate a return to the steady-state nominal GDP ratio following a trend-shifting shock. The trend equation for j = {c, inv, gc, x] is expressed as:

The equation is characterized by an autoregressive process. The second term defines the steady-state real growth rate for the corresponding expenditure item, whereas the third term introduces an error correction component, gradually guiding the trend back to the growth rate consistent with the steady-state nominal GDP ratio. Simultaneously, the real price trends ( Δ r p ¯ j ) are derived in conjunction with the GDP deflators. 27

The model pins down the potential GDP growth through the following autoregressive process:

With the potential GDP growth fixed in eq. 20, the domestic demand and export components are computed using eq. 19, while eq. 3 is employed to determine the real growth rate of the import trend.

3.1.2 Inflation and Aggregate Supply

The model allows for a range of empirically relevant nominal and real rigidities, often incorporated into central bank policy models, including price and wage stickiness. An important topic at this juncture, pertaining to destabilized inflation expectations risks and credibility concerns.

The headline inflation represented by the percentage changes in the consumer price index, in PAMPh is decomposed into core, food, and energy components. Core inflation aims to capture underlying inflationary pressure aligned with the cyclical position of the economy, while the latter two components describe non-core prices primarily influenced by international commodity prices and exchange rate fluctuations.

The consumer price index ( cpi ) identity is written as

Here, cpi food , cpi energy and cpi core represent the food, energy, and core consumer prices respectively, with w cpi,i denoting the corresponding weights from the Classification of Individual Consumption According to Purpose (COICOP) statistics. Despite the assumption of fixed weights in the CPI basket, these weights in COICOP statistics vary over time. The error term absorbs any unmodeled historical changes in weights.

PAMPh2.0 follows the FINEX model with the incorporation of real prices. All price levels are normalized by the headline CPI, expressing them in real terms, which can be further divided into gap and trend components. The trends are modeled as an exogenous autoregressive process, capturing permanent and medium-term price growth that exceeds the headline inflation target. The gaps are determined from the identities and fed into the Phillips curves. Relative price gaps are utilized to express pass-through among inflation components and assist in defining real marginal costs accurately.

Core inflation meets the essential criteria of the open-economy version of the New Keynesian Phillips curve, shaping inflation dynamics through the interplay of expectations and production costs:

It is driven by a hybrid of backward and forward-looking expectations, real marginal costs (rmc core ) , and the cost-push shock ( ε Δcpi core ). The expectations are endogenously determined by the series of real marginal costs and shocks. Real marginal costs encompass the cyclical position of the real economy, imported foreign inflation, and the inflationary pressure from non-core items. The cost function is expressed as:

The output gap serves as a proxy for domestic demand-side inflationary pressures, the second term reflects the international spillover effect of foreign inflation, and the last two terms involve the pass-through from non-core inflation to core inflation. Each term is formulated as the difference between the real effective exchange rate ( r e e r ^ ) or real price of non-core items ( r p ^ e n e r g y o r r p ^ f o o d ) and the real price of core ( r p ^ c o r e ) . These terms can be derived from nominal price differentials (see Al-Sharkas et al. (2023 )), constituting the real marginal costs in the core-sector. The extension of the labor market implies that the real wage ( w r ^ ) also contributes to firms’ production costs and, consequently, to the real marginal cost function.

The domestic prices of food and energy, considered as non-core items, adhere to the New Keynesian theory. The Phillips curve for these items incorporates both backward and forward-looking expectations, along with cost terms:

The cost terms are primarily driven by the international commodity prices adjusted by the bilateral exchange rate (USD vis a vis PHL, ( r e ^ t U S ) ) and deflated by the domestic commodity price level, and, as secondary, their own shocks. Energy prices are largely determined by the international Brent oil price, given that the Philippines is a net-oil importer. However, the idiosyncratic shock introduces additional, mostly domestic-driven, elements such as electricity, water and gas components in the energy CPI basket. The international commodity food price basket includes different products and different weightings; thus, the shock term absorbs these country-specific characteristics in domestic food prices.

Moreover, in alignment with Berg et al. (2023 ), the model incorporates Phillips curves for GDP-expenditure price deflators. These are interconnected with the respective expenditure gaps and the transmission / pass-through of imported inflationary pressures or international commodity prices. For details, see Appendix B.

3.1.3 Banking Sector

The model incorporates two types of credit—credit for households and credit for firms. Additionally, the model makes a clear distinction between the stock of credit (outstanding credit) and the flow of credit (newly issued bank loans).

The outstanding credit ratio, cr rat , is calculated as a fraction of the outstanding credit in the previous period and the newly issued credit ratio , ncr rat :

Δ j represents the share of outstanding credit that matured. Outstanding credit is further categorized into credit for households and firms, denoted by the index j = {h,f} . Both credit ratios, outstanding and newly issued, are expressed as shares of nominal potential GDP (denoted by g d p ¯ n o m ) 28 . ε cr rat denotes a shock.

The newly issued credit ratios are decomposed into a trend and a gap. The trend ratios are stochastic but returning gradually to a calibrated steady-state. The newly issued loan ratios in gap terms define the credit cycle. The shape of the gap equations differs for households and firms, reflecting the distinct purposes of loans.

Households demand credit primarily for consumption. The newly issued credit for household gap, denoted as n c r ^ h , r a t , is as follows:

c ^ represents a private consumption gap, r ^ L is a real lending rate gap, and Îľ n c r ^ h , r a t is a credit demand shock. Eq. 27 assumes that household loans are primarily utilized for consumption. Increased consumption, indicated by a positive consumption gap, results in higher demand for household credit. Conversely, a higher cost of credit, denoted by a positive real interest rate gap, implies a lower demand for credit.

Firms demand credit for investment in real estate, using housing as collateral. The newly issued credit gap equation for firms, n c r ^ f , r a t , is:

where z h ^ represents a relative house price gap, ncr f,ss,rat is the steady state share of newly issued credit to firms, ltv is the loan to value ratio, and ξ n c r ^ f , r a ⁢ t is a firm credit demand shock. The real lending rate gap serves as a measure of lending costs. Due to data availability constraints and for the sake of simplicity and tractability, the same real lending rate is utilized for households.

The demand for firm credit is influenced by changes in relative house prices, which serve as collateral, and the cost of credit. Firms’ credit is assumed to always be constrained by the value of collateral. Increasing property prices alleviate the binding constraint on the amount of credit; however, the gain in terms of collateral value is rescaled by the loan-to-value ratio (ltv) . Additionally, demand for newly issued loans is enforced to be only positive, not negative. This constraint is implemented using the maximum function in eq.28, preventing any potential decline of demand below the steady-state share of newly issued loans for firms.

The real lending rate as price of credit is computed from the nominal lending rate by substrating expected inflation. The nominal lending rate, denoted as rs L , has a 1-year maturity and is tied to the rate on one-year government bonds:

rs 1Y is one-year lending rate, prem c denotes credit premium, and Îľ rs L represents a shock to the lending rate. The credit premium is endogenous and comprises two parts:

Firstly, prem cc represents the risk component of the credit premium, necessary to factor in the probability of borrower default, and is determined by:

It assumes that the credit premium is negatively linked to the output gap, y ^ , and positively to the country risk premium gap, p r e m ^ . The negative impact of the output gap on the credit premium reflects the financial accelerator mechanism.

Secondly, the regulatory component of the credit premium denoted as bspread , represents the spread margin that banks add to meet capital requirements (discussed in detail below).

House prices are expressed in relative terms with respect to the GDP deflator. The relative price is further decomposed into a trend, denoted as z h ÂŻ , and a gap, represented by z h ^ .

z h ^ is determined by past and expected relative house prices, the business cycle position affected by the output gap, and the suppressing effects of the real lending rate gap.

Moving to banks, U/KBs are presumed to provide credit to the economy, with their assets assumed to remain relatively stable in relation to nominal potential GDP. This assumption is captured by the following equation:

Most assets are associated with the outstanding credit extended by banks, cr rat , and this portion is explicitly modeled. The remaining component, ta wedge , involves simple rescaling to align the nominal share with the data. To account for data affected by revaluation, a shock, Îľ ta , is introduced into the equation.

Commercial banks are required to maintain capital, which is represented as the ratio of capital to bank assets, denoted as bc ta . Capital accumulation is determined by the following process:

where ta represents total assets, roa return on assets, div ta share of dividends on total assets, and Îľ bc a shock to capital accumulation. Division by 400 transforms annualized growth of total assets to non-annualized qoq growth needed to capture bank capital accumulation as a share on total assets. According to eq.34, banks can accumulate capital in two ways: new capital can be issued, represented by the shock to capital accumulation, or capital can be accumulated from profits, increasing the return on assets.

The return on assets, roa , is estimated as the difference between the lending rate (in gauging profits) and the policy rate:

The added constant term, cost adj , accounts for the return/cost of other assets. The lending rate is determined by commercial banks, and the model assumes that these banks have the ability to adjust the lending rate spread, bspread , to accumulate capital if necessary.

b c t t a , T A R is the target level for capital on total assets and Îľ bspread is a shock to the spread set by commercial banks.

A third way how commercial banks can accumulate capital is by reducing dividend payments:

The function is nonlinear and ensures that no dividends are paid if the capital ratio (capital/assets) falls below the required target, and positive dividends are paid if the capital ratio is above the target. When capital requirements are met, dividends at the level div ss,ta are paid.

  • 3.2 External Balance

In the extended QPM, the BoP constraint is modeled explicitly, represented by the identity eq.38. The current account (net cross-border flows of goods and services) matches the financial account (net flows of financial claims)—generically, exports less imports together with private financial flows less FX purchases must equal zero. As highlighted in Berg et al. (2023 ), the PAMPh2.0 country application of FINEX embeds the structure of endogenous private financial flows (i.e., portfolio flows and cross border bank lending) responding to the uncovered interest parity (UIP) premium. 29

The current account is derived from the net export position ( nx rat ), remittance inflows ( remit rat ) in reference to income flow from Filipinos working abroad, interest payments on foreign currency (FCY) denominated public debt position ( intcost f,rat ), and other private foreign income ( oth rat ) which includes foreign interest payments on private net foreign asset and foreign direct investments:

As defined earlier, ‘ rat ’ superscript refers to variables expressed as a ratio of nominal GDP.

Financial account inflows ( fa rat ) are decomposed in eq.38, in helping determine the economy’s external financing needs commensurately with macroeconomic conditions:

Private sector financial inflows ( nfp rat ) are arrived at (residually) under derived fxi rat , fxa rat and the renewal of expired debt1Y f,rat 30 . The term exp( ) represents the exponential function. Since the terms are expressed in terms of period-t nominal GDP, the four-period lag term of foreign currency-denominated public debt is rescaled by the year-on-year nominal GDP growth and nominal depreciation.

Trend versions of eq.39 (defining for instance the equilibrium current account balance) and eq.40, and components therein (all denoted by bars), are defined below, in tracking the trend and gap parts of the current account and financial account balances.

The following equations describe the trend and cyclical position of financial inflows:

The terms p r e m ÂŻ and p r e m ^ denote country risk premium trend and gap positions respectively, and the Îľ p r e m ÂŻ and Îľ p r e m ^ are the corresponding shocks:

The total country risk premium feeds into the UIP condition. The UIP condition is the financial market equilibrium condition as the difference between the domestic ( i t M ) market interest rate and the foreign interest rate (i us ) is equal to the expected (nominal) exchange rate depreciation ( s t e − s t ) adjusted by the country risk premium (prem t ) . The f x i t r a t term captures the impact of central bank FX intervention policies. As the BSP increases foreign reserves, it generates higher demand for foreign assets, leading to a rise in domestic interest rates. An exogenous ( ε t s ) risk-on/off term is captured so is the willingness of foreign investors to supply financing which falls with higher reserves (a state-contingent component).

The expected nominal exchange rate is expressed as the weighted average of past and future nominal exchange rates:

The UIP condition can be interpreted in a way that determines the short-run position of the nominal exchange rate, where the expected nominal exchange rate is a combination of forward and backward-looking terms.

  • 3.3 Macroeconomic Policies

Extended QPMs motivated by the FINEX can accommodate a wide range of traditional and non-traditional policy instruments. The tools consist of a policy interest rate, FXI—to accumulate reserves and stabilize the exchange rate, MPMs, and CFMs, encompassing price-based and regulatory capital controls. BSP’s primary instrument is the overnight reverse repurchase (RRP) rate, it has also the ability to deploy FXI, CFMs, and MPMs. These are typically utilized in situations in which conventional interest rate policy might be constrained, taking a pragmatic approach, rather than following an explicit framework. The BSP’s flexible exchange rate regime has always been the first line of defense against financial market volatility and global shocks. However, the BSP may transact in the FX market to ensure orderly market conditions and to reduce excessive short-term volatility that could potentially have an impact on inflation and inflation expectations. From a fiscal policy perspective, various revenue- and expenditure-based instruments are guided by deficit and debt anchors to stabilize deficits and public debt. Other idiosyncratic policy adjustments are also part of the policy toolkit.

3.3.1 Monetary Policy

An interest rate reaction function aims to stabilize inflation and the output gap. Planned foreign exchange purchases can accumulate reserves to reach a prudent level, while FX interventions can help mitigate disorderly market conditions caused by, abrupt capital outflows for example. 31 Both price-based and regulatory CFMs can influence capital inflows directly. We describe the various instruments and channels pertinent to the specific policies and measures and highlight the interaction of policies in addressing trade-offs and reaching the central bank’s macro-financial and price stability objectives.

The policy interest rate

The BSP operates under a flexible inflation-targeting regime. The policy rate follows a standard Taylor rule (eq.46); it reacts to expected deviations of annual CPI (Δ 4 cpi t+2 ) from the target ( Δcpi TAR ) and to contemporaneous deviations of output from potential ( y ^ t ) .

The monetary rule also includes an autoregressive coefficient to prevent an immediate response of the policy rate, aligning with the historical volatility of the policy rate. Beyond the short-term horizon, the central bank sets the interest rate based on the neutral real interest rate and the inflation target. The shock to the policy rate (Îľ i Po1 ) allows for discretionary steps in monetary policy, deviating from systematic behavior.

The policy rate is translated to the market rates that affect the credit activity:

The money market rate (i M ) is determined based on the policy rate, with some delay. The BSP has traditionally used the unsecured IBCL rate as its primary indicator to guide open market operations. However, with the implementation of variable-rate RRP auctions in September 2023, the model adopted the overnight RRP rate as its principal market rate.

Foreign reserves management

The central bank in the model can manage the FX reserves level, through FX interventions aimed at influencing conjunctural outcomes (including in response to disorderly market conditions or excessive exchange rate volatility, and destabilizing impact of potential sharp exchange rate movements on macroeconomic and price stability) and/or by conducting systematic reserve accumulation to build stocks ( IMF 2023a ).

f x i t r a t is the central bank’s sterilized intervention to buy/sell reserves as a response to economic conditions 32 .

Based on eq.48, such rule-based interventions respond to exchange rate misalignments arising from current account deficits or real exchange rate overvaluation (the second and fourth terms), and to an interest rate differential (the third term) and captures money market disruptions reflected in the country risk premium. The first term allows for persistence. A discretionary FXI shock ( Îľ t f x i r a t ) allows for ad-hoc interventions. Rule (eq.48) is neither an optimal nor a systematic prescription for modeling FXI as a reaction function for the baseline projections and policy scenarios. From an operational perspective and model application, the rule is stylized and is meant to provide general guidance in demonstrating policy trade-offs and macroeconomic implications of various FX-intervention policies to specific shocks and its interactions with other policies monetary, macroprudential and fiscal policies.

In addition to FXI, the central bank uses FX accumulation ( f x a t r a t ) ) to steer the stock of foreign reserves towards a desired level. In eq.49, it is assumed that the BSP establishes an exogenous target for the optimal level of FX reserves relative to monthly imports. The accumulation of FX reserves ( fxa rat ) is then influenced by the response to the disparity between the actual FX reserves and the targeted threshold. Drawing from historical ARA-metric data, it is evident that the BSP has consistently maintained a substantial level of FX reserves. Since 2008, the ARA reserve ratio has consistently exceeded 150 percent. This ample reserve position has empowered the central bank to respond effectively to disorderly market conditions and external imbalances.

f x r e s ^ r a t i m p denotes the deviation of actual reserve in monthly imports from the targeted level, f x a ÂŻ r a t is the targeted reserve accumulation consistent with the FX reserve target. The central bank accumulates reserves, assumed in U.S. Tbills, where the total change of the FX reserve is the function of the sum of the intervention and accumulation, currency depreciation, and US Fed policy rate.

Eq.50 determines the reserve accumulation. A trend version of this equation underpinned by a fixed reserve target, determines the targeted FX accumulation:

Capital flow management

In the PAMPh framework, there is an option to incorporate CFMs, which can isolate domestic financial markets from global influences. These CFMs represent a potential strategy for stemming capital outflows and, consequently, shielding or alleviating the real economic repercussions of external shocks. Building on the framework established by Berg et al. (2023 ), we define two primary types of CFMs: (1) administrative restrictions and (2) capital inflow taxes.

Administrative restrictions, and in severe instances, outright bans, on cross-border transactions, denoted by ( τ t C F M , A d ⁢ min ⁡ ) , serve to diminish the sensitivity of endogenous capital flows or the private sector’s foreign financing requirements to the UIP premium ( p r e m ^ ) . Implicit in this approach is the imposition of limits on banks’ unhedged foreign exchange positions or foreign borrowing through administrative CFMs.

Capital inflow taxes elevate the cost of capital inflows. This characterization of CFMs is particularly relevant for market-based measures, such as imposing requirements to hold a portion of capital inflows as unremunerated reserves. These measures effectively heighten the excess return demanded by investors. We denote the capital flow CFM tax as ( τ CFM,flow ).

Formally, considering CFMs, eq.42 is adjusted as follows for n f p ^ r a t :

And correspondingly eq.41 for n f p ÂŻ r a t a n d p r e m ÂŻ :

CFMs, by restricting access to foreign financial markets (and potentially disconnecting domestic financial markets in extreme scenarios), exacerbate market shallowness. This is achieved by diminishing further the elasticity between the risk premium and the supply of private sector foreign financing. Consequently, CFMs can serve as an effective complement to FXI in mitigating nominal exchange rate pressures.

3.3.2 Macroprudential Policy

Banks adhere to regulatory macroprudential requirements defined by the ratio of capital to total assets. The ratio does not use risk-weighted assets and is simply taken to be a leverage ratio, i.e., capital to assets.

The target for the leverage ratio ( bc TAR ) is either maintained as a constant or set in a countercyclical fashion to smooth the credit cycle:

b c s s T A R represents the steady state level of the leverage ratio, ρ bc TAR indicates the degree of persistency in setting the instrument, and ε bc TAR represents a shock to the target level. The parameter ϕ indexes the strength of policy countercyclicality.

The structure of the above equation permits two modes of macroprudential policy—passive and active. By setting ρ bc TAR to 1, the target ratio remains constant, indicating that macroprudential policy does not respond to the credit cycle. Conversely, setting ρ bc TAR lower than one, along with nonzero ϕ , implies active macroprudential policy aimed at smoothing the credit cycle.

3.3.3 Fiscal Policy

Fiscal policy exerts influence over the short and medium-term trajectory of the real economy, inflationary pressures, and subsequently affects monetary policy decisions through various channels. In PAMPh2.0, we distinguish between different expenditure categories (such as current and capital expenditures, as well asfinancial transfers to households) and assume a single revenue source. The allocation of expenditures and revenue choices can have distinct implications for economic behavior and the response of monetary policy. Typically, expansionary fiscal expenditures tend to spur higher economic growth at the expense of inflationary pressures, necessitating a response from the central bank. However, the inflationary impact of fiscal spending hinges on the government’s choice of instrument—revenue mobilization or tax increases may initially dampen demand but ultimately aid in reducing public debt and foreign indebtedness, thereby contributing to lower country risk premiums and more accommodative medium-term monetary conditions. Furthermore, the interest rate set by the central bank can constrain the scope of fiscal policy. In environments characterized by higher inflation and interest rates, government debt service costs escalate, potentially challenging debt sustainability and prompting fiscal policy adjustments to generate surpluses or negative stimulus.

In this subsection, we explore the fundamental characteristics of the fiscal block and underscore the intricate interplay between fiscal and monetary policies.

As mentioned, the fiscal block aims to provide a simple yet empirically realistic account of government spending and revenue streams as well as government spending multipliers. In PAMPh, the fiscal block parsimoniously describes the government’s main objective, which is achieving and maintaining the targeted public debt level. 33 The total debt target is exogenously given as

The public debt can be further decomposed into local currency nominated (LCY) and foreign currency nominated (FCY) parts (see Berg et al. (2023 ), and Al-Sharkas et al. (2023 )). We assume a one-year maturity for the public debt for both FCY and LCY debt. New debt issuance follows the renewal of the expired debt level and the proportional financing of fiscal deficits. Meanwhile, total deficit (def rat ) is given by the primary deficit ( primdef rat , expenditures minus revenues) and the interest rate cost ( intcost rat , debt service of the FCY and LCY debts):

The government sets the structural deficit to anchor the public debt level around the target, considering that primary deficits are influenced by the economy’s cyclical position. Hence, defstruct rat represents the structural (cyclically adjusted) component, while defcycle rat captures the cyclical part of the primary deficit:

The cyclical part of the primary deficit follows a simple rule of thumb and links the budget position to the output gap:

where the negative sign is consistent with a common stylized fact: during economic upswings (positive output gap), the government tends to collect more revenues or needs to spend less on social expenditures and benefits, automatically generating a better deficit position and building buffers for bad times. The structural balance is determined by the fiscal rule that has two objectives:

As the primary objective, the government aims to stabilize the debt level, responding to the deviation from the targeted level ( d e b t ^ r a t ) until the debt reaches the target. As a second objective, the government also endeavors to support real economic activity by smoothing the cyclical position of the economy, maintaining GDP close to the potential level through countercyclical policies. In cases where the output gap position is negative, this approach permits a higher deficit, thereby minimizing the real economic sacrifice.

In light of the detailed primary deficit, the government must determine the instrument to be employed in achieving its fiscal objective. PAMPh2.0 provides a diverse set of instruments, including revenues ( rev rat ), financial transfers ( tr rat ), government current expenditures 34 ( gc rat ), and government capital expenditures ( gi rat ):

In our current calibration, it is assumed that the revenues automatically adjust to changes in the primary deficit, while the other components are exogenously determined by an autoregressive process. However, we are not limited to revenue as the sole instrument, and we can explore the impact of alternative consolidation strategies by employing different fiscal instruments. Furthermore, we can also compare the fiscal multipliers associated with various fiscal variables.

Debt service or interest expenditures are explicitly described in PAMPh 2.0 based on both domestic (LCY) and foreign (FCY) currency denominated debt. As a simplification, the 1-year maturity for both debts is assumed. The maturity transformation is based on the term structure of interest rates 35 described as follows:

where tprem d is the domestic term premium with steady-state denoted by tprem d,ss and Κ ¯ is the neutral level of interest rate computed as a sum of the natural rate of interest and the inflation target. The w c assigns the share of concessional debt, and we implicitly assume that the interest rate of the concessional debt is fixed at the natural interest rate plus steady-state term premium. The term tprem d is set by the financial markets which considers the level of domestic debt compared to its steady-state:

4. Model Properties, Calibration, and Historical Interpretation

PAMPh2.0 is, by design, a forecasting and policy analysis model. In this section, we demonstrate its use for this purpose, showing how it can provide a structural interpretation of the historical data, and help make policy-contingent forecasts and risk assessments. It highlights the range of fundamental and non-fundamental shocks. PAMPh2.0 can address and demonstrate policy interactions, taking into consideration specific (macroeconomics-financial) characteristics of the Philippines. Beyond single shocks and corresponding policy responses, the ability of PAMPh2.0 to incorporate complex shocks and analyze implications of combining traditional and non-traditional policy tools (FXI, CFMs, MPMs) is the hallmark of this practical policy model.

The subsections that follow aim to analyze the model’s dynamic properties with various exercises. First, in Section 4.1 the impulse response analysis describes the agent’s reaction to shocks and policy measures. As the next step, in Section 4.2, calibration and empirical validation demonstrate the model’s goodness of fit of the actual data. Finally, Section 4.2.3, illustrates the model behavior through the recent estimation of the cyclical position and interpretation of the actual economic data.

  • 4.1 Impulse Response and Scenario Analysis

The impulse response function describes the agent’s reaction to different shocks and provides insight into the dynamic properties of the model. Further, these assessments illustrate the benefits and costs of the interaction of different policies under particular shocks. These are basic elements of different policy scenarios where impulse responses are combined. In the following exercise, we show how scenarios can be simulated and the implications of different policy responses.

All simulations start from the steady state, with shocks causing deviations of model variables from this equilibrium. The figures depict the agents’ reactions and how the economy reverts to long-run equilibrium contingent upon a policy response. In all figures, variables are plotted as deviations from the initial steady-state equilibrium. 36 To illustrate, we showcase the effects of various scenarios, including the tightening policy by the US Fed with and without FX intervention and CFMs, an international food price shock linked to the El Nino phenomenon, a shock to private consumption, public debt consolidation, an increase in asset prices, and a wage shock.

4.1.1 US Fed Monetary Tightening

In this analysis, depicted in Figure 4.1 , we explore a scenario where the Fed opts for a more aggressive tightening of monetary conditions than necessary to maintain inflation at the target. Accordingly, this scenario involves an additional 100 basis point increase in the US Fed funds rate in the first quarter of 2024. The tightening of monetary conditions leads to a narrower foreign output gap and a slowdown in inflation. Additionally, the Fed’s actions lower foreign demand, further dampening foreign inflation and triggering capital outflows from emerging markets, thereby exerting depreciation pressure on other currencies. Consequently, the peso begins to depreciate, contributing to imported inflationary pressures.

The BSP faces two options to counteract this depreciation pressure and maintain inflation at the target. In the scenario without FXI, monetary authorities opt to raise the policy interest rate to mitigate depreciation pressures, resulting in a contraction in domestic demand over the next four years, thereby returning inflation to the target by early 2026. Given the shallowness of markets and prevailing disorderly market conditions, FXI could serve as an effective tool to alleviate depreciation pressure on the peso and counteract imported inflationary pressures. This approach necessitates milder depreciation and lower policy rate increases, resulting in a more limited economic contraction. However, we consider that FXI diminishes the BSP’s FX reserves and necessitates adequate sterilization capacities; otherwise, the decreasing liquidity could compromise the BSP’s control over domestic money market conditions.

US Fed Monetary Tightening

4.1.2 International Food Price Shock Associated with El NiĂąo

Figure 4.2 portrays the short-term repercussions of climate change and the El NiĂąo phenomenon, exemplified by heightened volatility in international food prices. Policymakers must consider the risk of rising world food prices, which could trigger a second-round effect on domestic inflation. 37 In this scenario, world food prices surge by 10 percent compared to the baseline projection and remain elevated until 2025. This commodity price shock promptly impacts domestic non-core food prices, resulting in higher headline inflation, prompting a monetary policy response from the BSP. Monetary policy initiates a tightening cycle to mitigate the secondary effects on other inflation components. However, this action comes at the cost of economic deceleration, dragging down the output gap. Tighter monetary conditions lead to reduced consumption and deteriorating terms of trade. Moreover, the tightening cycle induces disinvestment due to the higher cost of funding. The escalating import prices exacerbate the current account deficit, while heightened external financing intensifies pressure on risk premiums and the currency.

International Food Price Shock during El NiĂąo

4.1.3 Private Consumption Shock

In this scenario, domestic households temporarily increase consumption by 1 percentage point in the first quarter of 2024, achieved through reallocating future income and acquiring additional private credits. 38 This surge in consumption demand elevates the output gap and intensifies inflationary pressures particularly core inflation, necessitating further tightening measures from the BSP. The central bank responds by raising the policy rate to temper the heightened domestic demand and maintain domestic inflation close to the target.

Assuming no changes in foreign interest rates, the increased domestic interest rate prompts nominal appreciation of the peso against the dollar, immediately curbing non-core inflation. Subsequently, as demand recedes and peso appreciation persists, non-core inflation remains below the target, leading to a decline in core inflation and headline inflation falling below the target. The demand shock stimulates higher nominal growth and government revenues, temporarily aiding in reducing public debt. However, the initial surge in demand fuels imports, exacerbating the economy’s external position, heightening risk premiums, and constraining the monetary policy space to lower the nominal policy rate back to its original level.

Shock to Private Consumption

4.1.4 Public Debt Consolidation

In the aftermath of the COVID-19 shock, governments worldwide are endeavoring to restore gradually elevated public debt levels to those seen before the pandemic. In the case of the Philippines, the government has unveiled a gradual debt reduction strategy, aiming to reduce the deficit-to-GDP ratio to below 4 percent and lower public debt to about 56 percent of GDP by 2028. In our model, the government makes an exogenous decision regarding the targeted debt level. The adjustment toward this targeted level is delineated through the fiscal rule and the selected fiscal instrument.

This scenario, illustrated in Figure 4.4 , depicts the impact of a more ambitious fiscal consolidation, aiming to gradually reduce the debt target by 10 percentage points of nominal GDP during 2024, reaching a lower debt level by the end of 2025. 39 In this scenario, the government implements measures such as raising taxes as well as enhancing revenue mobilization to generate additional revenues (particularly from the relatively low level of tax-to-GDP ratio) and achieve a surplus in the primary balance.

The debt reduction process is gradual, taking eight quarters to reach the new target, and aligns with the fiscal rule, allowing for gradual adjustments in the primary surplus (termed “cyclical smoothing”) to prevent an overly restrictive fiscal stance and sharp economic slowdown. However, the reduction in household disposable income manifests in lower consumption levels and a contraction in the output gap. Subsequently, as the fiscal balance approaches neutrality and monetary policy maintains accommodative conditions, the output gap temporarily turns positive, accompanied by heightened inflation. The central bank responds by raising policy rates to guide inflation back to the target.

Furthermore, the debt consolidation strategy proportionally reduces the government’s foreign liabilities, enhancing the external financing position and diminishing risk premiums. This process generates appreciation pressures on the peso in the medium term.

Public Debt Consolidation

4.1.5 Asset Price Increase and Credit Boom

In Figure 4.5 , asset prices experience a permanent 10 percent increase, 40 leading to a credit boom fueled by the higher value of collateral. With heightened credit activity, the balance sheet of commercial banks (measured by outstanding credit to nominal GDP) expands, while the capital adequacy ratio declines, increasing exposure to systemic risks and vulnerability to a potential asset price downturn.

Under the scenario of ’Without Macroprudential’ policy, the target for the capital adequacy ratio remains unchanged. However, commercial banks are required to meet capital requirements, necessitating the generation of additional capital. The simulation assumes that this additional capital is generated through profits derived from higher lending rate margins. Although the higher lending rate gradually curtails the credit boom, it takes two years to restore the capital adequacy ratio to the required level. Monetary policy responds to the shock only to the extent that it poses a threat to price stability.

In the second scenario of the shock, labeled ’With Macroprudential’ , macroprudential policy responds to the heightened systemic risk by increasing the target for the countercyclical capital buffer. Commercial banks are required to meet the elevated capital requirements by accumulating more capital, which is achieved by generating profits through increased lending rates (while reducing dividend payments). The tighter lending conditions effectively neutralize the impact of the asset price shock, maintaining pressure on long-term asset prices and mitigating the spillover effect on actual economic activity. Consequently, monetary policy tightening is deemed unnecessary.

The disparity between the two scenarios underscores the effectiveness of macroprudential policy in addressing asset price bubbles, whereas monetary policy tools such as interest rates are less precise in this regard.

Asset Price Increase and Credit Boom

4.1.6 Risk Appetite Shocks

Figure 4.6 depicts the effects of a one-time negative 10 percentage point shock to risk appetite, generated by a shock to the country risk premium, resulting in an 8 percent nominal exchange rate depreciation in the initial scenario without FXI. In response to the resultant imported inflationary pressure, BSP reacts by tightening monetary conditions through an increase in the policy rate, leading to a contraction in real economic activity. Alternatively, the central bank may choose to sell FX reserves to alleviate immediate pressure on the exchange rate. 41 By doing so, the BSP could reduce the need for a substantial increase in the interest rate, thereby achieving price stability with a lower economic sacrifice. Moreover, if authorities impose CFMs on cross-border transactions to limit domestic agents’ access to foreign financial markets, the economy becomes more insulated from the adverse effects of an increase in the risk premium. In the short run, both CFMs effectively complement FX intervention, requiring lower FX intervention to achieve the same nominal exchange rate depreciation. However, in the medium term, due to administrative CFMs, the pressure on prices cannot be fully offset by economic contraction, leading to a more depreciated nominal exchange rate.

Shock to Country Risk Premium

4.1.7 Minimum Wage Increase Shocks

The simulation in Figure 4.7 presents the impact of a minimum wage increase on the economy. The shock to the minimum wage is equivalent to a year-on-year increase of about 4 percent, consistent with historical average minimum wage increase, implemented in Q4 2024. The simulation shows two scenarios: 1) no pass-through of minimum wage increase to the rest of the labor sector (orange line); and 2) partial pass-through of the minimum wage increase to business wages (blue line). In both scenarios, the additional wage hike boosts domestic demand through increased private consumption, leading to inflationary pressures. Higher wages likewise increase the marginal cost of firms that could result in additional price pressures, if passed on to consumers. The estimated impact is higher in the second scenario as it covers wage adjustments for the entire labor sector, as supposed to scenario 1 that assumes that only those receiving minimum wages will have additional income. Monetary policy responds by gradually tightening monetary conditions to bring inflation back to the targeted level.

Regarding its inflationary effects, the simulation aligns broadly with the Philippines version of the QIPF DSGE-model ( IMF 2023c ) in terms of magnitudes and signs of variable impulse responses. In standard DSGE-models, the consumption and GDP effects are typically close to neutral or negative because firms decrease labor demand, leaving household disposable income unchanged. Moreover, the reaction of monetary policy encourages intertemporal households to defer actual consumption decisions to stabilize inflation.

Shock to Minimum wage

4.2 Calibration and Empirical Validation of the Model 42

4.2.1 calibration: parameter categorization and iterative process.

The calibration process ensures that the model produces accurate and reliable results, including a good fit with historical data, accurate forecasting, economic coherence, the ability to explain historical events, and consistency of parameter values with econometric estimates. We establish clear criteria for assessing the calibration and define the consecutive stages of the calibration process as follows ( Berg et al., 2023 ): (i) defining the structure of PAMPh2.0; (ii) collecting and analyzing data; (iii) determining the parameters to be calibrated; and (iv) iteratively modifying parameter values to meet the specified criteria.

Throughout the calibration process, model-based assessments and forecasts must align with economic intuition and common institutional wisdom. This includes accurately estimating trends, cyclical components, and economic shocks.

In developing the PAMPh2.0 structure, a systematic approach is adopted, defining several steps and following a strategy in which each extension was gradually integrated into PAMPh’s initial version, requiring periodic review of calibration as the model evolved. The process unfolded as follows: initially, the GDP expenditure side decomposition was introduced as the first extension; subsequently, the model was enriched with a fiscal block; this was followed by the incorporation of an external balance block, endogenous country risk premia, FX intervention, and CFM policies; finally, the credit channel with macroprudential policies and the labor block were integrated.

At each stage, gradually introduced extended versions underwent rigorous testing using Philippine data and were subjected to discussions among staff members, including sector and data experts from other departments in the BSP. The pace of model development was also mindful of absorption capacity, as a richer model necessitates a more thorough and in-depth analysis of the economy and increased horizontal communication within the central bank.

Categorization of coefficients and parameters

Highlighting their distinct nature and methods of parametrization, coefficients and parameters are classified in three groups:

Calibration as distinct from estimation

The parameterization of semi-structural models involves a systematic process distinct from a standard Bayesian estimation. 44 Calibration exercises typically follow a three-step iterative process outlined in MATLAB with the IRIS Toolbox.

The primary advantage of this calibration approach lies in incorporating expert views. It allows model developers and policymakers to control coefficient values, ensuring proper interpretation of actual data. Calibration enables the integration of expert judgments and facilitates flexible treatment of incoming noisy (and short) data compared to estimation methods.

The calibration of PAMPh2.0 reflects the volatile nature of Philippine data. The relatively low values (mostly lower than 0.5) for backward-looking coefficients suggest a low persistence of inflation and real economic data. Consequently, macroeconomic variables are more susceptible to short-lived price shocks and commodity price shocks. 46 Additionally, the high volatility leads to relatively low values for elasticities, such as the interest rate elasticity in consumption gap or the output impact on core inflation compared to DSGE models. Conversely, the income channel exhibits greater strength, reflecting the relatively higher share of low-income and Keynesian households in the Philippines. The calibrated coefficients in the Taylor rule align closely with values found in the literature, 47 with a value of 1.5 for inflation deviation reaction, while the output gap reaction is 0.3. However, the interest rate smoothing is higher than benchmark values, indicating past behavior of the BSP to gradually change monetary policy settings.

Next subsections present in-sample simulations and the historical interpretation of the data as mentioned in calibration steps (ii) and (iii) above. Moreover, ex-post comparison of model based real-time forecasts with the actual data should be conducted to assess the model forecasting properties in real time exercise facing uncertainty and data revisions. However, this ex-post evaluation of the historical forecast evaluation can be conducted in the future when at least a year’s worth of PAMPh2.0-based historical quarterly forecasts are collected and more elaborate databases are developed.

4.2.2 Empirical Validation: In-Sample Simulations

It is essential to note that similar parameter values for policy reactions do not imply that the BSP follows the same strategy as other central banks used for benchmarking. While the BSP may align with the global monetary policy cycle driven by the Fed, its response can differ due to various transmission channels and unique country characteristics. The BSP retains autonomy to react differently to country-specific or foreign-originated shocks. For instance, imported inflation pressure from exchange rates and commodity price pass-through holds greater significance for the Philippines compared to the U.S. Given the substantial weight of food and energy prices, headline inflation in the Philippines is notably volatile. The BSP operates with a forward-looking rule and typically refrains from reacting to one-off, temporary price shifts as these inflationary spikes often fade quickly with muted second-round effects. Additionally, the central bank aims to minimize real economic losses by maintaining the output gap around neutral levels.

As part of the empirical evaluation of the model, we conducted in-sample simulations 48 (refer to Figure 4.8 ), where we assumed that foreign variables are observed and checked the model’s fit to domestic variables. Our findings indicate that the forecasted variables closely align with the observed data, capturing main turning points in the economy. Moreover, the model predictions exhibit minimal bias, with deviations from actual data remaining relatively small and changing sign over the forecast horizon, as reported in Table 4.1 . However, it is important to consider the conditionality of in-sample forecasts on policy responses when assessing the historical fit of the model. If the actual policy response differs from the policy conditions assumed in the forecast, the real model forecasts may diverge from actual data.

We can further assess the forecasting abilities of the PAMPh2.0 model by comparing the root mean squared errors (RMSE) with those of the random walk (RW) benchmark. A smaller RMSE ratio indicates that the PAMPh2.0 model provides superior forecasts, outperforming the RW benchmark for the respective variables and forecasting horizon.

Interestingly, for most variables and forecasting horizons, including volatile ones like inflation and GDP, the RMSE ratio is consistently better than the RW process, except for the current account deficit. Although the RMSE ratio for the current account deficit is higher, it remains very close to one, suggesting that while the RW process may offer a slightly better forecast, it cannot significantly outperform the PAMPh2.0 model. It is plausible that the current account has several unmodeled components outside the scope of the PAMPh2.0 model.

In-sample model simulations

Mean Errors and Root Mean Squared Errors relative to the Random Walk Process for selected variables

Mean Error RMSE Relative to Random Walk
1q 2q 3q 4q 5q 6q 1q 2q 3q 4q 5q 6q
Target RRP Rate (%) -0.05 -0.13 -0 19 -0.23 -0.26 -0.26 Target RRP Rate (%) 0 94 0 91 0 91 092 0 92 0 89
PHP per USD -0.29 -0.4 -0.43 -0.45 -0.46 -0.48 PHP per USD 0.83 0.70 066 0.61 0.59 056
Headline CPI (YoY %> -0 09 -019 -029 -0.38 -0.38 -0.35 Headline CPI (YoY %) 0.53 0.51 052 054 0.52 0 52
Real GDP (YoY %) -0 14 -0 18 -0 14 -0 05 0.22 0 38 Real GDP (YoY %) 0.47 058 059 0.61 0.75 072
Public Debt (% of GDP) 1 63 1 73 1.8 19 1 78 1.79 Public Debt (% of GDP) 0.87 069 053 0.43 0.38 0 33
Current Account Balance (% of GDP) -0.99 -1.13 -1.26 -1.33 -1.42 -1.48 Current Account Balance (% of GDP) 1 19 1 21 1.16 1 12 1 14 112

4.2.3 Empirical Validation: Historical Interpretation

As mentioned earlier, the evaluation of calibration and model performance can also be based on the historical interpretation of incoming data, including descriptions of estimated unobserved variables and structural shocks. These assessments collectively contribute to constructing a coherent economic narrative that elucidates underlying inflation pressures and shocks.

Using the Kalman filter, one can estimate unobserved variables (such as gaps and trends) and structural shocks based on observed time-series data. It is crucial to cross-check the gap and trend decomposition of key variables to ensure consistency with our interpretation of history—for example, understanding how the output gap contributes to high inflationary pressures. The filter also identifies structural shocks affecting the economy in each period. Additionally, we can test whether these shocks exhibit unbiased means and autocorrelations. 49

The model provides several results that help readers understand the economic story behind the observations. Different cross-plots examine the co-movement of observed and unobserved variables. For instance, core inflation may be driven by real marginal cost, or commodity price shocks may have a prevalent role in inflation dynamics during certain periods. By analyzing structural equations, we can demonstrate how each determinant contributes to the outcome variable. This exercise ultimately tests the importance of specific variables or channels; for example, if core inflation is primarily driven by domestic demand (output gap), we expect its contribution to be visible and significant. Additionally, shock decompositions for selected variables describe how structural shocks explain historical fluctuations of model variables. For instance, inflation may be driven by a combination of demand, supply, and foreign-originated shocks over the years. By aligning our economic interpretation of observed time-series data with model outcomes, we can verify the accuracy of our interpretations.

These exercises help form the narrative around the model. However, there is no formal statistical test that decides which calibration is “better” or provides a more adequate description of the examined economy. The economic story, based on filtration outcomes, is discussed by blocks, with the primary focus set on unobserved variables.

4.2.3.1 Inflation

With three exceptions, Philippine inflation fluctuated in the upper band of the inflation target during the observation period (see Figure 4.9 ). While core inflation remained relatively stable and smooth, fluctuations in food and energy prices contributed to spikes in the index. Before the GFC, before the COVID-19 crisis, and due to the Russia-Ukraine war, commodity price shocks pushed headline inflation above the high-end of the target band.

Core inflation describes the underlying inflationary trend in the economy. In Figure 4.10 , we illustrate how core inflation is influenced by the real marginal cost, which includes pressure from domestic demand, imported inflation, and the second-round effects of commodity price-driven domestic energy and food prices. As depicted in the figure, major trends in core inflation correspond to changes in real marginal cost. For instance, following the GFC, both real marginal cost and core inflation fluctuated below zero. Similarly, during recent inflationary pressures in 2022, a significant increase in real marginal cost was followed by a shift in core inflation.

Headline inflation and its breakdown, inflation % yoy and contributions in p.p .

Core inflation (yoy %, left axis) and real marginal costs (% right axis)

Additionally, the model can elucidate the primary components influencing the real marginal cost function, as shown in Figures 4.11 and 4.12 . The real marginal cost for core inflation is primarily influenced by fluctuations in the output gap and the spillover effects from non-core inflation. Except pre- and post-COVID-19 periods, import prices (a weighted average of trading partners’ inflation in USD) have either negatively impacted the marginal cost or remained neutral. In contrast, the real marginal costs for non-core inflation exhibit much higher volatility, reflecting the fluctuations in international commodity prices and the nominal exchange rate. Each spike in the estimated cost function corresponds to periods of elevated inflation, serving as a reliable predictor for non-core inflationary pressure.

Decomposition of real marginal costs for core inflation, %

Real marginal costs for non-core inflations, %

One can also illustrate how the estimated historical shocks contribute to the endogenous variables of the model. Figures 4.13 and 4.14 depict the historical shock decomposition of headline inflation and core inflation, both plotted as deviations from their targets. 50 This decomposition effectively highlights that model variables are influenced by various shocks, each contributing to different aspects of inflation dynamics. Given the Philippines’ status as an open economy with an open capital account and a freely floating exchange rate, foreign-originated shocks and financial shocks (such as exchange rate depreciation) play significant roles in both headline and core inflation, particularly evident before the GFC, in 2012, and during the post-COVID-19 recovery period. While supply shocks, including domestic-originated price shocks (primarily core or non-core cost-push shocks), also contribute to inflation dynamics, their influence is not as predominant. The impact of demand and fiscal shocks on core inflation is relatively limited, but their direction corresponds to periods of economic overheating before the GFC or economic slowdown during and after COVID-19.

Decomposition to shocks – Headline inflation deviation from the target, YoY %

Decomposition to shocks – Core inflation deviation from the implicit target, YoY %

4.2.3.2 Real Economic Activity

Besides the periods of the GFC and COVID-19, the Philippines’ GDP growth rate fluctuated around 6 percent, with the model estimating stable and high potential growth (see Figure 4.15 ). During the COVID-19 crisis, growth markedly slowed down, and the estimation reflects the specific nature of this period, with potential growth also decreasing in 2020. However, the economy has since recovered and continued its robust growth.

Figure 4.16 describes the output gap and its breakdown. The output gap is a key determinant of inflationary pressures and significantly affects inflation forecasts, indirectly influencing policymakers’ decision-making. Before the GFC, the output gap was positive, following a relatively neutral period. From 2016 until 2020, the output gap and inflationary pressures gradually intensified due to permanently loose global and domestic monetary conditions. The breakdown explains how each expenditure-side component has contributed to the fluctuations: household consumption and net exports play a major role in defining the underlying dynamics, while investment and government consumption gaps exhibit high volatility and generate temporary shifts in the output gap.

GDP and Potential Growth, YoY %

Output gap breakdown, pp

The consumption gap captures the domestic demand-related inflationary pressures, with its relatively large weight in the GDP, and it also determines a significant part of the output gap fluctuations. Figure 4.17 illustrates how the components of the consumption gap function determine the variables, while Figure 4.18 describes the historical shocks’ contribution to the cyclical variables.

Before the GFC period, consumption exceeded its potential level, generating inflationary pressures. It was mostly driven by a favorable income position, including improving net exports and loose foreign monetary conditions. Following the financial crisis, consumption was relatively stable and fluctuated around the neutral zero level. However, similarly to the output gap, the gap started to increase due to loose monetary conditions and an improving income position. During the COVID-19 crisis, all components, besides the shock, in eq.[x] contributed negatively to the gap. However, the model illustrates that after 2022, the loose monetary policy and recovery in economic performance increased the consumption gap back to positive values, explaining the inflationary pressure in 2023.

The shock decomposition describes a consistent story: the fluctuations were mostly explained by foreign, financial, and monetary policy shocks. However, the shock decomposition also highlights how many different shocks determined the consumption gap, with most of them offsetting each other.

Decomposition of Consumption gap, %

Decomposition to shocks – Consumption gap, %

Investment and its gap are highly volatile variables, with a significant portion of the cyclical changes explained by their own shock (see Figures 4.19 and 4.20 ). Consequently, the contribution of the portfolio channel or relative prices is limited, and even the timing of government capital expenditures does not correspond with increases in the investment gap.

Decomposition of Investment gap, %

Decomposition to shocks – Investment gap, %

The export gap is also a highly volatile variable primarily determined by foreign shocks or, in the equation decomposition, by the foreign demand components. Previously, we assumed that the Philippines’ exports are mostly driven by the semiconductor industry, which tends to be resilient to fluctuations in market share (such as changes in the real exchange rate and relative prices).

Decomposition of Export gap, %

Decomposition to shocks – Export gap, %

The import gap is calculated as the sum of the weighted average of GDP demand-side components and its own shock. Given that the Philippine traded sector relies heavily on imports, the export gap plays a significant role in determining imports, while other components also contribute but to a lesser extent (see Figure 4.23 ). The shock decomposition in Figure 4.24 paints a similar picture: a large portion of the import gap is determined by foreign shocks (including export and import shocks), while other variables also influence imports through domestic demand components, albeit to a lesser degree.

Decomposition of Import gap, %

Decomposition to shocks – Import gap, %

4.2.3.3 Fiscal Policy

Before the COVID-19 crisis, the government pursued a successful debt consolidation strategy, reducing the national debt from 60 to 40 percent of nominal GDP (see Figure 4.25 ). However, during the COVID-19 crisis, the government financed increased expenditures by issuing more debt, causing public debt to rise to 60 percent of GDP. 51 Beginning in 2022, the fiscal authority opted to consolidate the debt level and reduce the total deficit. Figure 4.26 illustrates the components of the total deficit, which align with debt accumulation. The successful debt consolidation before the COVID-19 crisis coincided with decreasing debt service and a negative primary deficit (surplus). Additionally, favorable global monetary conditions post-GFC supported reduced debt service and the debt consolidation strategy. Conversely, following the COVID-19 crisis, the primary deficit significantly increased before gradually decreasing again from 2022.

Debt to GDP ratio, level and target decomposition, % of GDP

Government balance and its components, % of GDP

The structural deficit, representing the cyclically-adjusted primary deficit, reflects the fundamental stance of fiscal policy. As shown in Figure 4.27 , the structural deficit closely tracked the primary deficit due to the relatively closed output gap. However, during the COVID-19 crisis, the disparity between these deficits widened, although by the end of the analyzed period, the structural deficit approached the primary deficit closely. The breakdown of the primary deficit ( Figure 4.28 ) elucidates the dynamics of its main components. The government steadily augmented its revenue through improved revenue mobilization. Prior to the COVID-19 crisis, fiscal policy maintained relatively stable levels of current expenditure and transfer expenditures, while gradually boosting capital expenditures. In response to the COVID-19 crisis, the government escalated health-related and additional capital expenditures to mitigate the crisis’ adverse effects. From 2022 onward, these supplementary measures began to be phased out gradually.

Primary Deficit and estimated Structural Deficit, % of GDP

Decomposition of primary deficit, % of GDP

4.2.3.4 Monetary Policy and Credit Channel

Assessing the stance of monetary policy requires an understanding of the medium-term dynamics of monetary conditions, such as the trend of the real interest rate or the natural real interest rate. In open economies, the trend of the real interest rate is influenced by factors including the foreign real interest rate trend, country risk premium trend, and the expected appreciation of the real exchange rate. Figure 4.29 illustrates the real effective exchange rate and its trend. Before the GFC, these trends followed the typical pattern observed in other emerging economies. During the period of the great moderation, strong capital inflows and expansion of the traded sector led to an appreciation of the real exchange rate. However, this trend slowed down after 2010, and the real exchange rate trend flattened, with short-term pressures on the peso evident. Between 2016 and 2019, nominal depreciation translated into real depreciation.

The estimated country risk premium derived from the UIP equation is closely linked to the external financing position and the current account deficit, as depicted in Figure 4.30 . Following the GFC, there was a notable uptick in the country risk premium after a period of gradual decline. During the taper tantrum period (2016–2019), nominal depreciation of the peso was driven by capital outflows and an elevated country risk premium. After the recovery from the COVID-19 pandemic and amidst a new era of global monetary tightening, further pressure on external balances emerged, leading to an increase in the country’s risk premium.

Real Effective Exchange rate and its trend, %

Current Account (% of GDP) and Estimated Country Risk Premium and its trend, %

The real interest rate and its deviation from the trend illustrate the relative tightness of monetary policy, as shown in Figure 4.31 . When the level exceeds the trend (positive real interest rate gap), monetary policy is considered contractionary, negatively impacting the output gap. The decomposition below reveals that before the financial crisis, the central bank pursued a contractionary policy to stabilize inflation. Later, it shifted to a neutral and slightly expansionary stance in response to prolonged financial turmoil. However, from 2015 onward, it maintained an expansionary stance, with the real interest rate gap turning negative as it may not have responded sufficiently to increasing country risk premiums. The expansionary stance of policy is in line with intensifying inflationary pressures in this period. The onset of COVID-19 prompted a shift in monetary stance, with the BSP gradually reducing interest rates to support economic activity and counter the pandemic’s adverse effects. After the recovery period in 2022, as inflationary pressures intensified, the central bank raised interest rates to align the real interest rate level with the trend and mitigate the positive output gap. The decomposition of the real interest rate trend indicates that its variability is primarily driven by the country risk premium and real exchange rate trend. These variations reflect the Philippines exposure to global financial market flows.

Figure 4.32 decomposes the nominal interest rate based on the Taylor rule, corroborating the narrative presented in the previous figure. The Taylor rule is calibrated to reflect historical monetary policy decisions aligned with the primary objective. The yellow bars correspond to periods when inflation exceeded the target, prompting BSP to increase the policy rate. Additionally, the figure illustrates instances of monetary policy deviations from the systematic rule: between 2016 and 2018 and in 2022, when relatively accommodative conditions were maintained, the model identifies negative monetary policy shocks.

Real Interest Rate and its trend with components, %

Decomposition of Monetary Policy Rate, %

Finally, the financial block of the model provides further insights into the development of the credit channel. Figure 4.33 illustrates the private sector credit stock as a percentage of nominal GDP. Following the GFC period, credit activity, particularly on the firms’ side, became buoyant, supporting real economic growth. This significant credit expansion was facilitated by relatively accommodative monetary conditions and declining lending rates. Figure 4.34 shows that lending rates primarily decreased due to lower government bond rates (related to the monetary policy rate) and narrowing credit risk premiums. However, crisis periods such as the GFC and COVID-19 temporarily disrupted this trend, leading to increased credit risk premiums. Further, beginning in 2022, the credit growth markedly slowed down and began to decrease due to tightening monetary conditions and rising lending rates, reflecting the contractionary policy stance of the central bank.

Private Credit Stock, % of GDP

Decomposition of Lending Rate, %

  • 5. Conclusion

The modernization initiative spearheaded by the BSP through the development of the Forecasting and Policy Analysis System (FPAS), featuring the semi-structural Quarterly Projection Model known as PAMPh2.0, represents a pivotal step towards equipping policymakers with a robust analytical tool for real-time decision-making amidst the intricacies of the macro-financial landscape. This endeavor, bolstered by the collaborative efforts with the IMF and guided by ICD-led technical assistance, signifies the BSP’s commitment to leveraging advanced modeling techniques. Through iterative enhancements and extensions, PAMPh2.0 delivers forward-looking projections, incorporating endogenous monetary and fiscal policies, macrofinancial linkages, labor market dynamics, and additional tools such as FX intervention, fostering integrated thinking and coordination among various policy tools within the BSP.

The modernization drive extends beyond the core model to encompass essential reforms in pivotal elements of the FPAS, essential for effectively navigating the complexities of the multi-policy environment and facilitating informed policy deliberations. Moreover, a clear plan guiding activities towards the formal adoption of PAMPh2.0 underscores the BSP’s unwavering commitment to model-based, data-driven decision-making.

Impulse response analysis has highlighted the structural interpretation of historical data within PAMPh2.0, enabling policy-contingent forecasts and risk assessments. By demonstrating the model’s adaptability to a range of both fundamental and non-fundamental shocks, while accounting for the unique characteristics of the Philippines’ macroeconomics and finance, it offers valuable insights into policy implications across different scenarios. This comprehensive understanding of the model’s behavior supports informed policy decision-making. The recent application of the model to simulate the minimum wage increase scenario could effectively assist policymakers in understanding the various consequences of a wage hike, thereby enriching discussions about the risks to the inflation outlook.

The calibration process of the PAMPh2.0 model has ensured its accuracy and reliability by aligning with historical data, maintaining economic coherence, and leveraging institutional insights. This systematic approach involved incorporating various model extensions and undergoing rigorous testing and discussions among staff, allowing for the integration of expert views and flexibility in managing the volatile nature of Philippine data. Historical interpretation, supported by the Kalman filter, has played a pivotal role in constructing a coherent economic narrative, examining variable co-movement, and verifying the alignment of economic interpretations with model outcomes. The model enabled the policy advisor to reconcile and consistently explain the background of pre- and post-COVID-19 demand-side pressures, while also highlighting the contribution of the delayed monetary policy reaction to the intensifying inflationary pressure.

While no formal statistical test was conducted to determine the superiority of one calibration over another, these empirical exercises have been vital for constructing a coherent narrative around the model and validating its accuracy by aligning economic interpretations with model outcomes. In-sample simulations have offered empirical evidence of the model’s performance, showing its effectiveness in capturing key turning points of domestic variables with minimal bias. For example, the model effectively captured the BSP tightening cycle before and after the COVID-19 periods, aligning consistently with the inflationary pressure. Notably, deviations from actual data are relatively small and tend to change signs over the forecast horizon, further enhancing confidence in the model’s predictive capabilities.

In conclusion, the formal adoption of PAMPh2.0 not only provides staff and policymakers with a robust tool but also fosters the development and institutionalization of coordination among monetary, financial supervision, and macroprudential sectors within the BSP. This facilitates the assessment of business cycles and monetary policy stances, quantification of policy effects, understanding of trade-offs, and alignment with long-term objectives. In particular, the model has proven to be a valuable forecasting and policy analysis tool, especially in light of the recent surge in inflation. As PAMPh2.0 becomes the preferred core model for policy deliberation, its dynamic nature enables future refinements to align with evolving theoretical thinking and empirical findings.

Adrian , T. , C.J. Erceg , M. Kolasa , J. Lindé , and P. Zabczyk , 2021 . “ A Quantitative Microfounded Model for the Integrated Policy Framework ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2021/292 (December) .

  • Search Google Scholar
  • Export Citation

Al-Sharkas A. , N. Al-Azzam , S. AlTalafha , R. A. Shawish , A. Shalein , A. Rawwaqah , A. Al-Rawashdeh , D. Baksa , P. Karam , and J. Vlcek , 2023 . “ An Extended Quarterly Projection Model for the Central Bank of Jordan ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2023/172 (August) .

Aguiar , M. , and G. Gopinath , 2007 . “ Emerging Market Business Cycles: The Cycle Is the Trend ,” Journal of Political Economy 115 , no. 1 (2007) : 69 – 102 .

Basu , S. S. , E. Boz , G. Gopinath , F. Roch , and F. D. Unsal , 2020 . “ A Conceptual Model for the Integrated Policy Framework ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2020/121 .

Basu , S. S. , E. Boz , G. Gopinath , F. Roch , and F. D. Unsal , 2023 . “ Integrated Monetary and Financial Policies for Small Open Economies ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2023/161 (August) .

Basu , S. S. , and G. Gopinath , 2024 . “ An Integrated Policy Framework (IPF) Diagram for International Economics ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2024/038 (February) .

Berg , A. Y. , Hul , P. , Karam , A. , Remo , and D. Rodriguez , 2023 . “ Forecasting Model of Internal and External Balance ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2023/235 .

Chinn , M. D. , and H. Ito , 2006 . “ What Matters for Financial Development? Capital Controls, Institutions, and Interactions ,” Journal of Development Economics , Volume 81 , Issue 1 , Pages 163 – 192 ( October ).

Chen , J. , R. A. Espinoza , C. Goncalves , T. Gudmundsson , M. Hengge , Z. Jakab , and J. Lindé , 2022 . “ Effective Fiscal-Monetary Interactions in Severe Recessions ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2022/170 (September) .

Chung , H. T. , M. T. Kiley , and J. Laforte , 2010 . “ Documentation of the Estimated, Dynamic, Optimization-based (EDO) Model of the U.S. Economy: 2010 Version ,” Finance and Economics Discussion Series, Divisions of Research & Statistics and Monetary Affairs Federal Reserve Board , Washington, D. C. , 2010 – 29 .

Fernández , A. , M. W. Klein , A. Rebucci , M. Schindler , and M. Uribe , 2016 . “ Capital Control Measures: A New Dataset ,” IMF Economic Review , Palgrave Macmillan; International Monetary Fund , Vol. 64 ( 3 ), pages 548 – 574 , August .

Gabaix , X. , and M. Maggiori , 2015 . “ International Liquidity and Exchange Rate Dynamics ,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, President and Fellows of Harvard College , Vol. 130 ( 3 ), pages 1369 – 1420 .

Guo , S. , P. Karam , and J. Vlcek , 2019 . “ Decomposing the Inflation Dynamics in the Philippines ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2019/153 (July) .

IMF , 2022 . “ The Philippines: Selected Issues .” Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, Country Report No. 2022/370 .

IMF , 2023a . “ Integrated Policy Framework – Principles for the Use of Foreign Exchange Intervention .” Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund .

IMF , 2023b . “ The Philippines: 2023 Article IV Consultation .” Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, Country Report No. 2023/414 .

IMF , 2023c . “ The Philippines: Selected Issues .” Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund, Country Report No. 2023/454 .

Karam , P. , M. Pranovich and J. Vlcek , 2021 . “ An Extended Quarterly Projection Model: Credit Cycle, Macrofinancial Linkages and Macroprudential Measures: The Case of the Philippines ,” IMF Working Paper No. 2021/256 (October) .

Karam , Musil , and Vlcek , 2024 . “ An Extended QPM with Labor and Wages .” Forthcoming IMF WP .

Mæhle , N. , Hlédik , T. , Selander, C and M. Pranovich , 2021 . “ Taking Stock of IMF Capacity Development on Monetary Policy Forecasting and Policy Analysis Systems ”, IMF Discussion Paper, No. DP/2021/026 (December)

Okun , A. M. , 1962 . “ Potential GNP, its measurement and significance”. Cowles Foundation, Yale University .

Tobin , J. and W.C. Brainard , 1977 . “ Asset Markets and the Cost of Capital .” In: Fellner, W., Balassa, B.A. and Nelson R. R., Eds., Economic Progress, Private Values and Public Policy, Essays in Honor of William Fellner, North-Holland Publishing Company, Amsterdam, 235–262 .

  • Appendix A: Model Variables

Real Aggregate Demand

Code Name Unit
GDP: Real volume level
GDP: Real volume 100*log
GDP: Gap dev. from its trend
GDP: Trend 100*log
GDP: Real volume , QoQ changes, annualized
Y GDP: Real volume , YoY changes
GDP: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
GDP: Trend , YoY changes
Private Consumption: Real volume level
Private Consumption: Real volume 100*log
Private Consumption: Gap dev. from its trend
Private Consumption: Trend 100*log
Private Consumption: Real volume %, QoQ changes, annualized
c Private Consumption: Real volume %, YoY changes
Private Consumption: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Private Consumption: Trend %, YoY changes
Private Consumption: Nominal ratio of nominal GDP
Private Consumption: Nominal ratio trend of nominal GDP trend
Total Investment: Real volume level
Total Investment: Real volume 100*log
Total Investment: Gap dev. from its trend
Tobin-Q
Total Investment: Trend 100*log
Total Investment: Real volume , QoQ changes, annualized
inv Total Investment: Real volume %, YoY changes
Total Investment: Trend %, QoQ changes, annualized
Total Investment: Trend , YoY changes
Total Investment: Nominal ratio of nominal GDP
Total Investment: Nominal ratio trend of nominal GDP trend
Gov. Consumption: Real volume level
Gov. Consumption: Real volume 100*log
Gov. Consumption: Gap % dev. from its trend
Gov. Consumption: Trend 100*log
Gov. Consumption: Real volume , QoQ changes, annualized
gc Gov. Consumption: Real volume , YbY changes
Gov. Consumption: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Gov. Consumption: Trend %, YoY changes
Gov. Consumption: Nominal ratio % of nominal GDP
Gov. Consumption: Nominal ratio trend % of nominal GDP trend
Export: Real volume level
Export: Real volume 100*log
Export: Gap % dev. from its trend
Export: Trend 100*log
Export: Real volume %, QoQ changes, annualized
x Export: Real volume %, YoY changes
Export: Trend %, QoQ changes, annualized
Export: Trend %, YoY changes
Export: Nominal ratio % of nominal GDP
Export: Nominal ratio trend % of nominal GDP trend
Import: Real volume level
Import: Real volume 100*log
Import: Gap % dev. from its trend
Import: Trend 100*log
Import: Real volume %, QoQ changes, annualized
m Import: Real volume %, YoY changes
Import: Trend %, QoQ changes, annualized
Import: Trend %, YoY changes
Import: Nominal ratio % of nominal GDP
Import: Nominal ratio trend % of nominal GDP trend

Labor market block

Cods Name Unit
Nominal Business Wage level
Nominal Business Wage lOCTlog
Nominal Business Wage QoQ changes, annualized
w Nominal Business Wage YoY changes
Nominal Minimum Wage level
Nominal Minimum Wage lOCTlog
Nominal Minimum Wage QoQ changes, annualized
w Nominal Minimum Wage YoY changes
Nominal Average Wage level
Nominal Average Wage lOCTlog
Nominal Average Wage QoQ changes, annualized
w Nominal Average Wage YoY changes
Nominal Wage: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Nominal Wage: Trend , YoY changes
Real Wage 10Q*log
Real Wage: Gap dev. from its trend
Real Wage: Trend 10Q*log
Real Wage: Trend QoQ changes, annualized
Real Wage: Trend YoY changes
Private Consumption: Real volume 10Q*log
Private Consumption: Gap dev. from its trend
Private Consumption: Trend 10Q*log

Banking sector and credit block

Cods Name Unit
Outstanding Credit % of nominal GDP
Outstanding Credit: Households % of nominal GDP
Newly Issued Credit for Households % of nominal GDP
Newly Issued Credit for Households: Gap % of nominal GDP
Newly Issued Credit for Households: Trend % of nominal GDP trend
Outstanding Credit: Firms % of nominal GDP
Newly Issued Credit for Firms % of nominal GDP
Newly Issued Credit for Firms: Gap % of nominal GDP
Newly Issued Credit for Firms: Trend % of nominal GDP trend
Nominal credit rate
Real credit rate
Real credit rate: Gap
Real credit rate: Trend
Real credit rate: HP-Trend
Credit premium
Market risk premium of credit
Borrower default-risk
Asset prices
Commercial Bank capital accumulation % of nominal GDP
Return on Assets
Dividend of commercial banks % of Total Assets
Total Assets Target % of nominal GDP trend
Total assets of commercial banks 100*log
Total assets of commercial banks % of nominal GDP trend
Credit costs % of nominal GDP trend
Total assets of commercial banks , QoQ changes, annualized

Aggregate Supply

Cods Name Unit
CPI: Headline index 100*log
CPI: Headline %, QoQ changes, annualized
cpi CPI: Headline %, YoY changes
CPI: Core index 100*log
CPI: Core %, QoQ changes, annualized
cpi CPI: Core %, YoY changes
Real marginal cost: Core
CPI: Non-Core, Food index 100*log
CPI: Non-Core, Food %, QoQ changes, annualized
cpi CPI: Non-Core, Food %, YoY changes
Real marginal cost: Non-Core, Food
CPI: Non-Core, Energy index 100*log
CPI: N on-Core, Energy %, QoQ changes, annualized
cpi CPI: Non-Core, Energy %, YoY changes
Real marginal cost: Non-Core, Energy
CPI: Level Shock to the index 100*log
Relative price of Core: Index 100*log
Relative price of Core: Gap % dev. from its trend
Relative price of Core: Trend 100*log
Relative price of Core: Trend %, QoQ changes, annualized
Relative price of Food: Index 100*log
Relative price of Food: Gap % dev. from its trend
Relative price of Food: Trend 100*log
Relative price of Food: Trend %, QoQ changes, annualized
Relative price of Energy: Index 100*log
Relative price of Energy: Gap % dev. from its trend
Relative price of Energy: Trend 100*log
Relative price of Energy: Trend %, QoQ changes, annualized

GDP Deflators

Code Name Unit
Deflator: Private Consumption index 100*log
Deflator: Private Consumption , QoQ changes, annualized
p Deflator: Private Consumption , YoY changes
Relative price of P.Cons. Deflator: Index 100*log
Relative price of P.Cons. Deflator: Gap % dev. from its trend
Relative price of P.Cons. Deflator: Trend 100*log
Relative price of P.Cons. Deflator: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Deflator: Investment index 100*log
Deflator: Investment , QoQ changes, annualized
p Deflator: Investment , YbY changes
Real Marginal Cost: Investment deflator 100*log
Relative price of Inv. Deflator: Index 100*log
Relative price of Inv. Deflator: Gap % dev. from its trend
Relative price of Inv. Deflator: Trend 100*log
Relative price of Inv. Deflator: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Deflator: Gov. Cons, index 100*log
Deflator: Gov. Cons. , QoQ changes, annualized
p Deflator: Gov. Cons. , YoY changes
Real Marginal Cost: Gov. Cons, deflator 100*log
Relative price of Gov. Cons. Deflator: Index 100*log
Relative price of Gov. Cons. Deflator: Gap % dev. from its trend
Relative price of Gov. Cons. Deflator: Trend 100*log
Relative price of Gov. Cons. Deflator: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Deflator: Export index 100*log
Deflator: Export , QoQ changes, annualized
p Deflator: Export , YoY changes
Real Marginal Cost: Export deflator ioa*iog
Relative price of Export Deflator: Index 100*log
Relative price of Export Deflator: Gap dev. from its trend
Relative price of Export Deflator: Trend 100*log
Relative price of Export Deflator: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Deflator: Import index ioa*iog
Deflator: Import QoQ changes, annualized
p Deflator: Import %, YoY changes
Real Marginal Cost: Import deflator 100*log
Relative price of Import Deflator: Index lOCTlog
Relative price of Import Deflator: Gap dev. from its trend
Relative price of Import Deflator: Trend ioa*iog
Relative price of Import Deflator: Trend QoQ changes, annualized
Deflator: GDP index 100*log
Deflator: GDP , QoQ changes, annualized
p Deflator: GDP , YoY changes
Relative price of GDP Deflator: Index 100*log
Relative price of GDP Deflator: Gap dev. from its trend
Relative price of GDP Deflator: Trend 100*log
Relative price of GDP Deflator: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Nominal GDP: index 100*log
Nominal GDP , QoQ changes, annualized
gdp Nominal GDP , YoY changes
Nominal GDP: Trend 10Q*log
Nominal GDP: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Nominal GDP: Trend , YoY changes

Monetary policy

Cods Name Unit
Real exchange rate (with USD): Index 100*log
Real exchange rate (with USD): Gap % dev. from its trend
Real exchange rate (with USD): Trend 100*log
Real exchange rate (with USD): Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Real eff. exchange rate: Index 100*log
Real eff. exchange rate: Gap % dev. from its trend
Real eff. exchange rate: Trend 100*log
Real eff. exchange rate: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Implicit Headline CPI target , QoQ changes, annualized
Implicit Core CPI target , QoQ changes, annualized
Implicit Non-Cor, Food CPI target , QoQ changes, annualized
Implicit Non-Cor, Energy CPI target , QoQ changes, annualized
BSP Target RRP Rate
Market Interest Rate
Real Interest Rate
Real Interest Rate: Gap
Real Interest Rate: Trend
Nominal exchange rate: Index (PHL/USD) 100*log
Nominal exchange rate , QoQ changes, annualized
s Nominal exchange rate , YoY changes
Nominal exchange rate: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Nominal exchange rate: Trend , YbY changes
Country Risk Premium
Country Risk Premium: Gap
Country Risk Premium: Trend
FX- Interventions % of nominal GDP
FX-reserve accumulation % of nominal GDP
FX-reserve accumulation: Trend % of nominal GDP trend
FX-reserve: Total % of nominal GDP
FX-reserve: Trend % of nominal GDP trend
FX-reserve: Total in months of import
FX-reserve: Trend in months of import
FX-reserve: Gap in months of import
CFM: Administrative, tax rate
CFM: Price-based, tax rate

Balance of payment

Code Name Unit
Current Account: Nominal ratio total % of nominal GDP
Current Account: Nominal ratio trend of nominal GDP trend
Current Account: Nominal ratio gap % of nominal GDP
Net Export: Nominal ratio total % of nominal GDP
Net Export: Nominal ratio trend of nominal GDP trend
Net Export: Nominal ratio gap % of nominal GDP
Remittances: Nominal ratio total % of nominal GDP
Remittances: Nominal ratio trend of nominal GDP trend
Remittances: Nominal ratio gap % of nominal GDP
Other foreign income: Nominal ratio total % of nominal GDP
Other foreign income: Nominal ratio trend of nominal GDP trend
Other foreign income: Nominal ratio gap % of nominal GDP
Financial Account: Nominal ratio total % of nominal GDP
Financial Account: Nominal ratio trend of nominal GDP trend
Financial Account: Nominal ratio gap % of nominal GDP
Private sector foreign financing: Nominal ratio total % of nominal GDP
Private sector foreign financing: Nominal ratio trend of nominal GDP trend
Private sector foreign financing: Nominal ratio gap % of nominal GDP

Fiscal variables

Cods Name Unit
Debt service: Total of nominal GDP
Debt service: Total of nominal GDP trend
Debt service: LCY of nominal GDP
Debt service: LCY of nominal GDP trend
Debt service: FCY of nominal GDP
Debt service: FCY of nominal GDP trend
1Y LCY Interest rate
1Y LCY Interest rate: Trend
1Y LCY Term premium
1Y FCY Interest rate
1Y FCY Interest rate: Trend
1Y FCY Term premium
Public Debt: Total of nominal GDP
Public Debt: Total Target of nominal GDP trend
Public Debt: LCY of nominal GDP
Public Debt: LCY Target of nominal GDP trend
Public Debt: FCY of nominal GDP
Public Debt: FCY Target of nominal GDP trend
Public Debt: LCY of nominal GDP
Public Debt: LCY Target of nominal GDP trend
Public Debt: FCY of nominal GDP
Public Debt: FCY Target of nominal GDP trend
Government Balance: Total of nominal GDP
Government Balance: Target of nominal GDP trend
Primary Deficit: Total of nominal GDP
Primary Deficit: Cyclically Adjusted of nominal GDP
Primary Deficit: Cyclically Part of nominal GDP
Debt deviation term of nominal GDP
LCY Financing share K/1O0
Primary Deficit: Target of nominal GDP trend
Total Revenue of nominal GDP
Total Revenue: Gap of nominal GDP
Total Revenue: Trend of nominal GDP trend
Total Expenditures of nominal GDP
Total Expenditures: Gap of nominal GDP
Total Expenditures: Trend of nominal GDP trend
Current Expenditures of nominal GDP
Current Expenditures: Gap of nominal GDP
Current Expenditures: Trend of nominal GDP trend
Capital Expenditures of nominal GDP
Capital Expenditures: Gap of nominal GDP
Capital Expenditures: Trend of nominal GDP trend
Transfers of nominal GDP
Transfers: Gap of nominal GDP
Transfers: Trend of nominal GDP trend
Other Expenditures of nominal GDP
Other Expenditures: Gap of nominal GDP
Other Expenditures: Trend of nominal GDP trend

Foreign variables

Cods Name Unit
Oil price: Index, USD 100*log
Relative price of oil: Index lOCTlog
Relative price of oil: Gap dev. from its trend
Relative price of oil: Trend ioa*iog
Relative price of oil: Trend , QoQ changes, annualized
Food price: Index, USD ioa*iog
Relative price of food: Index 100*log
Relative price of food: Gap dev. from its trend
Relative price of food: Trend 100*log
Relative price of food: Trend %, QoQ changes, annualized
US FED Interest rate %
US Real Interest Rate
US Real Interest Rate: Gap
US Real Interest Rate: Trend
Effective Foreign Prices in USD 100*log
Effective Foreign Demand
CPI in Country j: Headline index ioa*iog
CPI in Country j: Headline %, QoQ changes, annualized
cpi CPI in Country j: Headline %, YoY changes
Output Gap in Country j of potential GDP
Nominal Ex. Rate j vis-a-vis USD ioa*iog
Nominal Ex. Rate j vis-a-vis USD %, QoQ changes, annualized
Real Ex. Rate j vis-a-vis USD
Real Ex. Rate j vis-a-vis USD %, QoQ changes, annualized

Shocks in the model

Code Name Unit
Shock to Consumption Gap
Shock to Nominal Business Wage
Shock to Nominal Wage
Shock to Real Wage Trend
Shock to Unemployment Gap
Shock to Unemployment Trend
Shock to Gov. Consumption Gap
Shock to Investment Gap
Shock to Export Gap
Shock to Export Gap
Shock to Potential Growth Rate
Shock to Consumption Trend
Shock to Gov. Consumption Trend
Shock to Investment Trend
Shock to Export Trend
Shock to Households Outstanding Credit
Shock to Firms Outstanding Credit
Shock to Households’ New Credit gap
Shock to Households’ New Credit trend
Shock to Firms’ New Credit gap
Shock to Firms’ New Credit trend
Shock to Credit Rates
Shock to Market Risk Premium
Shock to Default Risk Premium
Shock to Total Assets
Shock to Asset Prices
Shock to Bank Capital
Shock to Return on Asset ratio
Shock to Dividend
Shock to Bank Capital Total Asset Ratio
Shock to Headline CPI weights
Shock to Core CPI
Shock to Non-Core, Food CPI
Shock to Non-Core, Energy CPI
Shock to Relative Core Price Trend
Shock to Relative Food Price Trend
Shock to Consumption Deflator
Shock to Relative Cons. Deflator Trend
Shock to Gov. Cons. Deflator
Shock to Relative Gov. Cons. Deflator Trend
Shock to Investment Deflator
Shock to Relative Inv. Deflator Trend
Shock to Export Deflator
Code Name Unit
Shock to Relative Export Deflator Trend
Shock to Import Deflator
Shock to Relative Import Deflator Trend
Shock to GDP Deflator
Shock to Relative GDP Deflator Trend
Shock to Real Exchange Rate Trend
Shock to Remittances Trend
Shock to Remittances Gap
Shock to Other Income Trend
Shock to Other Income Gap
Shock to Monetary Policy Rate
Shock to Market rate
Shock to Nominal Exchange Rate
Shock to Risk Premium Gap
Shock to Risk Premium Trend
Shock to FX-intervention
Shock to Reserve Accumulation
Shock to FX-re serve Trend
Shock to Administrative CFM
Shock to Flow CFM
Shock to LCYTerm Premium
Shock to FCYTerm Premium
Shock to 1Y LCY New Debt issuance
Shock to 1Y FCY New Debt issuance
Shock to Total Deficit
Shock to Cyclically Adjusted Primary Deficit
Shock to Public Debt Target
Shock to LCY Debt issuance share
Shock to Oil Price Trend
Shock to Oil Price Gap
Shock to Food Price Trend
Shock to Food Price Gap
Shock to Other Fiscal Expenditures
Shock to Government Investment
Shock to Government Transfer
Shock to US FED Interest Rate
Shock to US Real Interest Rate Trend
Shock to Trading partners CPI
Shock to Trading partners Output Gap
Shock to Trading partners NER
Shock to Trading partners RER

Appendix B: Model Equations

  • B.1 Real Aggregate Demand

Consumption gap equation:

Investment gap equation:

Tobin-Q equation:

Government consumption gap equation:

Export gap equation:

Import gap equation:

Potential GDP growth:

Consumption trend growth:

Investment trend growth:

Government consumption trend growth:

Export trend growth:

Import trend growth:

Gap and trend identities:

Annualized q-o-q growth rates:

Y-o-Y growth rate:

Great ratios (in nominal GDP):

Great rations in for trends (in nominal trend GDP):

Output gap:

  • B.2 Labor Market Block

Nominal Business Wage Phillips Curve:

Minimum wage:

Average nominal wage:

Growth of trend real wage:

Okun’s law, the unemployment rate gap:

NAIRU, non-accelerating rate of unemployment:

  • B.3 Banking Sector and Credit Block

Outstanding credit:

Households’ outstanding credit:

Firms’ outstanding credit:

Total new credit:

Households’ new credit gap and trend decomposition:

Households’ new credit gap (demand):

Households’ new credit trend (demand):

Firms’ new credit gap and trend decomposition:

Firms’ new credit gap (demand):

Credit interest rate (demand):

Credit real interest rate:

Credit real interest rate decomposition:

Credit real interest rate HP-trend

Credit real interest rate trend

Credit premium:

Market Risk Premium of Credit:

Borrower default-risk:

Asset prices:

Total assets of the commercial banks:

Commercial Bank capital accumulation:

Return on Assets:

Lending rate spread:

Dividend to Total Assets:

Total Asset target:

Credit costs:

Total assets in terms of nominal GDP:

  • B.4 Aggregate Supply

Headline CPI:

Level shock to CPI-components:

Core inflation Phillips-curve:

Real marginal cost of core inflation:

Food inflation Phillips-curve:

Energy inflation Phillips-curve:

Relative price of core CPI:

Trend and gap decomposition of relative price of core CPI:

Core CPI relative price trend:

Implicit inflation target for Core CPI:

Relative price of food CPI:

Trend and gap decomposition of relative price of food CPI:

Food CPI relative price trend:

Implicit inflation target for food CPI:

Relative price of energy CPI:

Trend and gap decomposition of relative price of energy CPI:

Energy CPI relative price trend:

Implicit inflation target for energy CPI:

Q-o-Q changes of CPIs and relative price:

Y-o-Y changes of CPI:

  • B.5 GDP Deflators

Consumption deflator (measurement equation):

Investment deflator Phillips-curve:

Real marginal cost of investment deflator:

Government consumption deflator Phillips-curve:

Real marginal cost of government consumption deflator:

Export deflator Phillips-curve:

Real marginal cost of export deflator:

Import deflator Phillips-curve:

Real marginal cost of import deflator:

Relative price gap of GDP deflator:

Relative price trend of GDP deflator:

Relative price trend of consumption deflator:

Relative price trend of investment deflator:

Relative price trend of government consumption deflator:

Relative price trend of export deflator:

Relative price trend of import deflator:

Relative price of deflators:

Trend and gap decomposition of relative price of deflators:

Nominal GDP:

Nominal GDP trend:

  • B.6 Real Interest Rate and Exchange Rate

Real interest rate identity:

Real exchange rate (PPP) identity:

Real exchange rate trend:

Real exchange rate gap:

Q-o-Q change of Real exchange rate trend

Real uncovered interest rate parity condition:

Real interest rate gap:

Bilateral real exchange rate gap vis-Ă -vis with USD:

Bilateral real exchange rate trend vis-Ă -vis with USD:

Effective foreign price in USD:

Implicit depreciation trend (PPP condition with trends):

Annual growth rate of nominal exchange rate trend:

  • B.7 Balance of Payments

Balance of payment identity:

Balance of payment identity (trend):

Current account:

Current account trend:

Current account gap:

Net-export:

Net-export trend:

Net-export gap:

Total remittances:

Remittances trend:

Remittances gap:

Other foreign net income:

Other foreign net income trend:

Other foreign net income gap:

Financial account gap:

Private sector net foreign financing position:

Private sector net foreign financing position trend:

Foreign credit supply, gap:

Foreign credit supply, trend:

  • B.8 Monetary Policy

Taylor-rule:

Market rate:

UIP condition:

Nominal exchange rate expectation

Country risk premium:

FX-reserve target:

FX-reserve accumulation:

FX-reserve gap:

FX-reserve consistent accumulation trend:

Q-o-Q changes of nominal exchange rate:

Y-o-Y changes of nominal exchange rate:

FX-reserve in months (Adequacy ratio):

FX-reserve trend in months (Adequacy ratio trend):

Administrative CFM:

Price-based CFM:

  • B.9 Fiscal Policy

B.9.1 Government Expenditures Total expenditures without debt service:

Sum of central and local government current expenditures:

Local government current expenditures:

Government capital expenditures:

Government financial transfers:

Total expenditures without debt service in trend:

Sum of central and local government current expenditures in trend:

Local government current expenditures trend:

Government capital expenditures trend:

Government financial transfers trend:

Expenditure gaps:

Total debt service:

LCY debt service:

1Y LCY interest rate:

1Y LCY term premium:

1Y FCY debt service:

1Y FCY interest rate:

1Y FCY term premium:

B.9.2 Government Revenues Total revenues from the primary deficit

Total revenues from the structural deficit

Total revenue gap:

Total revenue trend:

B.9.3 Debt Accumulation Total public debt:

Total 1Y LCY debt:

Total 1Y FCY debt:

1Y LCY new debt issuance:

1Y FCY new debt issuance:

B.9.4 Fiscal Anchor, Deficits and Reaction Functions Government deficit:

Primary deficit:

Primary deficit (cyclical):

Cyclically adjusted primary deficit:

Debt deviation:

Share of LCY financing:

B.9.5 Fiscal Targets Public debt target:

Total public debt target:

LCY public debt target:

FCY public debt target:

LCY targeted new issuance:

FCY targeted new issuance:

Targeted total debt service:

LCY targeted debt service:

LCY long term interest rate:

FCY targeted debt service:

FCY long term interest rate:

Primary deficit target:

  • B.10 Foreign Variables

Relative price of oil:

Relative price of food:

US CPI Phillips curve:

Q-o-Q US CPI:

Y-o-Y US CPI:

US FED policy rate:

US real interest rate:

US GDP gap:

US real interest rate gap:

US real interest rate trend:

Other trading partners output gap, exchange rate, inflation and real exchange rate j = {EZ,CN,JP,RC}

Effective foreign demand gap:

  • Appendix C: Parameters
Code Value Parameter role Calibration choice and justification
Consumption gap lag term Iterative adjustment
Consumption gap forward looking term Iterative adjustment
0.12 Elasticity of the consumption gap wrt monetary conditions Iterative adjustment
0.25 Weight of real lending rate gap in monetary conditions Iterative adjustment
Additional effect of country risk premium on domestic financing conditions Iterative adjustment
0.15 Elasticity of the consumption gap wrt income Iterative adjustment
Weight of trems-of-trade in consumption gap Iterative adjustment
0.05 Elasticity of the consumption gap wrt the remittances Iterative adjustment
0.05 Elasticity of the consumption gap wrt government taxation Iterative adjustment
0.08 Elasticity of the consumption gap wrt real wage gaps Iterative adjustment
0.05 Elasticity of the consumption gap wrt credit shock Iterative adjustment
0.36 Investment gap lag term Iterative adjustment
Investment gap forward looking term Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the investment gap wrt Tobin-Q Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the investment gap wrt relative price investment Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the investment gap wrt government investment Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the investment gap wrt credit shock Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the Tobin-Q. wrt expected income Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the Tobin-Q. wrt expected asset price Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the Tobin-Q wrt monetary conditions Iterative adjustment
0.5 Weight of real interest rate gap in monetary conditions Iterative adjustment
0.3 Weight of real credit rate gap in monetary conditions Iterative adjustment
0.5 Tobin-Qforward looking term Iterative adjustment
0.5 Gov. Consumption gap lag term Iterative adjustment
0.6 Export gap lag term Iterative adjustment
0.025 Elasticity of the export gap wrt real effective ex. rate Iterative adjustment
0.5 Elasticity of the export gap wrt export price Iterative adjustment
1.5 Elasticity of the export gap wrt foreign demand Iterative adjustment
0.4 Import gap lag term I/O tables
0.36 Weight of consumption gap in import Iterative adjustment
0.025 Price elasticity of the import gap wrt real exchange rate I/O tables
0.06 Weight of gov. consumption gap in import I/O tables
0.27 Weight of investment gap in import I/O tables
0.9 Potential growth persistence Iterative adjustment
0.5 Consumption trend persistence Iterative adjustment
0.25 Consumption trend error-correction term Iterative adjustment
0.5 Investment trend persistence Iterative adjustment
0.6 Investment trend error-correction term Iterative adjustment
0.5 Gov. consumption trend persistence Iterative adjustment
0.6 Gov. consumption trend error-correction term Iterative adjustment
0.8 Export trend persistence Iterative adjustment
0.1 Export trend error-correction term Iterative adjustment
5.8269 Steady-state potential GDP growth Historical average
74 Consumption in terms of GDP Historical average
23 Investment in terms of GDP Historical average
10 Gov. consumption in terms of GDP Historical average
27 Export in terms of GDP Historical average

Labor Market

Code Value Parameter role Calibration choice and justification
Nominal Business Wage lag term Iterative adjustment
0.05 Wage wrt Marginal Rate of Substitution Iterative adjustment
Weight of the consumption gap in Marginal Rate of Substitution Iterative adjustment
Weight of the real wage gap in Marginal Rate of Substitution Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of Nominal Business Wage wrt Minimum Wage Increase Iterative adjustment
Weight of Minimum Wage in Total Wage index Historical average
Real Wage Trend lag term Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the real wage trend wrt potential growth Iterative adjustment
0.85 Unemployment gap lag term Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the unemployment gap wrt output gap Iterative adjustment
Unemployment Trend lag term Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the unemployment trend wrt potential growth Iterative adjustment
Steady-state real wage growth Historical average
Steady-state unemployment ratio Historical average

Credit and Banking Sector

Code Value Parameter role Calibration choice and justification
0.1 Duration of Households’ Outstanding credit Iterative adjustment
0.15 Duration of Firms’ Outstanding credit Iterative adjustment
0.25 Households’ New credit gap lag term Iterative adjustment
0.05 Elasticity of Hh. New Credit Gap wrt Consumption Gap Iterative adjustment
0.025 Elasticity of Hh. New Credit Gap wrt Real Credit Rate Gap Iterative adjustment
0.4 Firms’ New credit gap lag term Iterative adjustment
0.75 Loan to Value Ratio Iterative adjustment
0.2 Elasticity of Firms New Credit Gap wrt Real Credit Rate Gap Iterative adjustment
Credit Rate lag term Iterative adjustment
1600 HP-filter coefficient Iterative adjustment
0.8 Weight of HP trend Iterative adjustment
0.5 Market risk premium lag term Iterative adjustment
0.1 Elasticity of Market risk premium wrt Output gap Iterative adjustment
0.25 Elasticity of Market risk premium wrt Country Risk Premium Iterative adjustment
0.1 Elasticity of Borrower Default Risk wrt Bank Capital gap Iterative adjustment
0.5 Asset price lag term Iterative adjustment
0.95 Borrowers’ discount factor Iterative adjustment
0.2 Elasticity of Asset Price wrt Domestic demand Iterative adjustment
0.5 Elasticity of Asset Price wrt Real Credit Rate Iterative adjustment
0 Reaction to credit deviation from steady-state ratio Iterative adjustment
0.92 Households’ New Credit trend lag term Iterative adjustment
0.9 Firms’ New Credit trend lag term Iterative adjustment
0.75 Total Asset target lag term Iterative adjustment
12 Targeted bank capital to asset ratio Historical average
45 Total Credit ratio Historical average
Reserve Requirement Ratio Historical average
Dividend to Asset ratio Historical average
1.55 Market risk premium Historical average
0.9 Share of firms’ credit in total credit Historical average
Code Value Parameter role Calibration choice and justification
0.2137 Weight of food items in CPI CPI database
0.0819 Weight of energy items in CPI CPI database
0.2 Core CPI lag term Iterative adjustment
0.05 Elasticity of the core inflation wrt output gap Iterative adjustment
0.01 Elasticity of the core inflation wrt real effective exchange rate Iterative adjustment
0.005 Elasticity of the core inflation wrt domestic energy price Iterative adjustment
0.005 Elasticity of the core inflation wrt domestic food price Iterative adjustment
0.05 Elasticity of the core inflation wrt real wage Iterative adjustment
0.25 Food CPI lag term Iterative adjustment
0.066 Elasticity of the food inflation wrt international food prices Iterative adjustment
0.25 Energy CPI lag term Iterative adjustment
0.18 Elasticity of the food inflation wrt international oil prices Iterative adjustment
0.75 Relative food price trend lag Iterative adjustment
0.75 Relative core price trend lag Iterative adjustment
0 Steady-state relative core price growth Historical average
Steady-state relative food price growth Historical average
Code Value Parameter role Calibration choice and justification
0.25 Error correction term In consumption deflator equation Iterative adjustment
0.4 Investment deflator lag term Iterative adjustment
0.2 Elasticity of the investment deflator wrt real marginal cost Iterative adjustment
0.2 Weight of investment gap in real marginal cost by investment deflator equation Iterative adjustment
0.05 Weight of oil price gap in real marginal cost by investment deflator equation Iterative adjustment
0.3 Gov. consumption deflator lag term Iterative adjustment
0.3 Elasticity of the gov. consumption deflator wrt real marginal cost Iterative adjustment
0.6 Weight of gov. cons, gap in real marginal cost by gov. cons, deflator equation Iterative adjustment
0.05 Weight of oil price gap in real marginal cost by gov. cons, deflator equation Iterative adjustment
0.3 Export deflator lag term Iterative adjustment
0.4 Elasticity of the export deflator wrt real marginal cost Iterative adjustment
0.6 Weight of export gap in real marginal cost by export deflator equation Iterative adjustment
0.1 Weight of oil price gap in real marginal cost by export deflator equation Iterative adjustment
0.3 Import deflator lag term Iterative adjustment
0.4 Elasticity of the import deflator wrt real marginal cost Iterative adjustment
0.4 Weight of import gap in real marginal cost by import deflator equation Iterative adjustment
0.189 Weight of oil price gap in real marginal cost by import deflator equation Iterative adjustment
0.1 Weight of food price gap in real marginal cost by import deflator equation Iterative adjustment
0.5 Relative consumption deflator price trend lag Iterative adjustment
0.75 Relative investment deflator price trend lag Iterative adjustment
0.75 Relative gov. consumption deflator price trend lag Iterative adjustment
0.9 Relative export deflator price trend lag Iterative adjustment
0.9 Relative import deflator price trend lag Iterative adjustment
-0.5 Steady-state relative consumption deflator growth Historical average
-1 Steady-state relative investment deflator growth Historical average
0 Steady-state relative gov. consumption deflator growth Historical average
-1.25 Steady-state relative export deflator growth Historical average
-1 Steady-state relative import deflator growth Historical average

Balance of Payments and Monetary conditions

Code Value Parameter role Calibration choice and justification
0.25 Weight of inflation expectations Iterative adjustment
0.35 Effectiveness of FX-interventlon on Nominal Exchange rate Iterative adjustment
Weight of nominal exchange rate expectations Iterative adjustment
0.85 Real exchange rate trend lag Iterative adjustment
Remittances trend lag Iterative adjustment
Remittances gap lag Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the remittances gap wrt foreign effective demand gap Iterative adjustment
Other income trend lag Iterative adjustment
Other income trend gap Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the premium gap wrt private sector capital flow Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the premium trend wrt private sector capital flow Iterative adjustment
Premium trend lag term Iterative adjustment
Code Value Parameter role Calibration choice and justification
Interest rate smoothing Iterative adjustment
Responsiveness of BSP to Inflation deviation Iterative adjustment
Responsiveness of BSP to Output gap Iterative adjustment
Market rate lag term Iterative adjustment
FXI-rule lag term Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the FX-intervention wrt current account Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the FX-intervention wrt reserve requirement Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the FX-interventlon wrt risk premium Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the FX-intervention wrt real exchange rate gap Iterative adjustment
FXA-rule lag term Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the FX-accumulation wrt reserve requirement Iterative adjustment
Forward-lookingness of FXA-rule Iterative adjustment
FX-reserve target lag term Iterative adjustment
Administrative CFM lag term Iterative adjustment
Price based CFM lag term Iterative adjustment
Steady-state relative real app. Historical average
Steady-state remittances Historical average
Steady-state other income Historical average
1.25 Steady-state risk premium Historical average
Steady-state FX reserve ratio (in month of imports) Historical average
Steady-state Administrative CFM Historical average
Steady-state Price-based CFM Historical average

Fiscal policy

Code Value Parameter role Calibration choice and justification
Other gov. expenditures lag term Iterative adjustment
Government investment lag term Iterative adjustment
Government transfer lag term Iterative adjustment
Share of concessional financing Iterative adjustment
LCY term-premium lag Iterative adjustment
FCY term-premium lag Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the LCY term-premium wrt LCY indebtedness Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the FCY term-premium wrt FCY indebtedness Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the primary deficit wrt output gap Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the fiscal reaction function wrt output gap Iterative adjustment
Elasticity of the fiscal reaction function wrt debt deviation Iterative adjustment
Weight of actual debt deviation in fiscal reaction function Iterative adjustment
Smoothing of fiscal reaction function Iterative adjustment
Share of LCY financing lag term Iterative adjustment
Steady-state other gov. expenditure Historical average
Steady-state government investment Historical average
Steady-state government transfer Historical average
Steady-state public debt target (annual GDP) Historical average
Steady-state LCY term-premium Historical average
Steady-state FCY term-premium Historical average
Steady-state LCY financing Historical average
Code Value Parameter role Calibration choice and justification
0.95 Real price of oil trend lag term Iterative adjustment
0.7 Real price of oil gap lag term Iterative adjustment
0.95 Real price of food trend lag term Iterative adjustment
0.7 Real price of food gap lag term Iterative adjustment
0.8 USCPI lag term Iterative adjustment
0.8 US FED policy rate lag term Iterative adjustment
, 0.9 US output gap lag term Iterative adjustment
0.99 US neutral rate lag term Iterative adjustment
0.125 Weight in Foreign Demand Historical average
0.25 Weight in Effective Foreign CPI Historical average
1 Steady-state US real interest rate Historical average
2.4693 Steady-state US CPI target Historical average
0 Steady-state growth of real price of oil Historical average
0 Steady-state growth of real price of food Historical average

Other trading partners demand, cpi, bilateral nominal and real ex. rate

Code Value Country Weight( )
0.90 Eurozone 0.082
0.85 China 0.220
0.85 Japan 0.138
0.90 Rest of the world 0.435
0.70 Eurozone 0.13
0.90 China 0.17
0.60 Japan 0.20
0.60 Rest of the world 0.25
0.95 Eurozone 0.00
0.95 China -1.00
0.95 Japan 0.00
0.95 Rest of the world 0.00
0.40 Eurozone
0.40 China
0.40 Japan
0.40 Rest of the world
0.80 Eurozone 2.00
0.80 China 2.00
0.70 Japan 0.00
0.52 Rest of the world 3.00

The original basic QPM or PAMPh v1.0 (Policy Analysis Model for the Philippines) is described in Alarcon et al. (2021).

For example, in reference to key IPF frictions (UIP premia distortions, FX mismatches, unanchored inflation expectations), the underlying destabilizing effects are concerns that have been addressed in the context of structural and semi-structural models to different degrees, following different approaches.

PAMPh2.0 acknowledges other types of models which focus on similar objectives of policy analysis and forecasting—for e.g., DSGE-type models for these purposes. See Maehle et al. (2021) and Berg et al. (2023 ) for a comparison of models broadly; and the Philippines, for comparing the two types as pertaining to the Philippines ( IMF 2023b ).

A statistical evaluation of forecasts involves computing statistical characteristics like bias and RMSE during the early stages of forecasting with PAMPh. Recognizing the conditionality of PAMPh forecasts on the policy interest rate, deviations from actual data may result, primarily affecting the near-term horizon. However, such deviations do not need to be interpreted as model imprecisions but rather deviations caused by different monetary policy response.

The model features and structure of PAMPh was presented during the 61 st Philippine Economic Society Annual Meeting and Conference on 7 November 2023.

Average basic daily pay is the pay for normal time, prior to deductions of social security contributions, withholding taxes, and others. It excludes allowances, bonuses, commissions, overtime pay, and benefits in kind.

The time series include the size of the adult population, number of employed, underemployed, visibly underemployed, wage and salary workers, unpaid family workers, weekly mean hours worked, real minimum wage, and real average basic daily pay.

Supply-side shocks include shocks to inflation expectations, which can be assessed by referring to Figure 4.13 for a historical shock decomposition and its contribution to inflation dynamics.

The financial cycle indicator is constructed using model variables: the credit gap, the interest rate spread between lending and policy rates, and property price growth. Each variable carries equal weight in the indicator.

The average bank lending rate refers to the average of U/KBs’ reported quoted or indicative high/low lending rates as reported in the Interest Rates on Loans and Deposits (IRLD) survey. Prior to 2020, the said rate is based on reporting U/KBs’ interest income and outstanding peso-denominated loans.

The funding costs of banks are also affected by reserve requirements and other government regulations. Furthermore, the yields on long-term government securities are also influenced by the level of indebtedness and country risk premium.

Bayanihan to Heal as One Act or Republic Act (R.A.) No. 11469 was enacted on 24 March 2020.

Bayanihan to Recover as One Act or R.A. No. 11494 was enacted on 11 September 2020.

Such programs include the Social Amelioration Program, the COVID-19 Adjustment Measure Program, and the Small Business Wage Subsidy Program. The funds were sourced from pooled savings through the discontinuation of government projects that were appropriated during the budget formulation. Source: Annual Fiscal Report 2020.

In 2024, the government reviewed the program and revised the deficit target to 3.7 percent for 2028, along with adjusting the debt-to-GDP target to 55.9 percent for the same year.

Source: GPMN website

This paper does not draw broad policy lessons or identify shortcomings in forecasting or policy analysis models, unlike Basu and Gopinath (2024) , who review Mundell-Fleming and suggest changes for comprehensive policies under financial frictions, which we integrate into our practical policymaking model.

A central bank wields a policy interest rate, possibly complemented with FXI and CFMs. The government sets various fiscal instruments.

Based on Karam, Musil, and Vlcek, 2024 “An Extended QPM with Labor and Wages.” (Forthcoming IMF WP).

In the so-called PAMPh2.0 gap model, an important characteristic is that the economy evolves around an underlying, but well-defined, equilibrium path. The gaps develop when the economy deviates from such path, in general caused by a variety of shocks. The role of monetary policy is to assist in closing the gaps by guiding the economy back to its equilibrium path, importantly, inflation back to its target.

The relative price is calculated as the GDP deflator divided by the CPI. Following Berg et al. (2023 ), the relative prices can be split into gap and trend components. Relative price gaps enter equations describing the cyclical position of the economy and relative price trends are used to express the medium-term great ratios in terms of nominal GDP trend.

The export and import trend ratios are time-variant coefficients reflecting the real importance of the export and import sector of Philippines.

The choice of deflator for computing the real wage depends on the model structure. Either the GDP deflator, consumption deflator, or CPI can be utilized.

The System of National Accounts (SNA) encompasses the total public consumption of the public sector, including both the central government and municipalities. In contrast, the Government Finance Statistics (GFS) focuses solely on central government spending. In the calculation of GDP identities, we utilize the government consumption from SNA.

In our model, formally, we do not explicitly distinguish between producer currency pricing (PCP) and dominant currency pricing (DCP). However, implicitly, we assume that exporters follow DCP, as they exhibit resistance to real exchange rate movements. This is indicated by the fact that exporters’ import demand remains independent of exchange rate fluctuations. Additionally, in the export demand curve, the low coefficient for the real exchange rate suggests that most exporters set their optimal prices in foreign currency and do not adjust them based on domestic currency fluctuations.

The I/O tables describe how different branches and sectors of the economy contribute to total production, gross domestic product (GDP), and the final use of income (GDP expenditure side). These tables also quantify the import demand of each branch. Assuming a linear production technology, the import demand in final usage can be calculated from the total import demand of the branches and their contributions to final use.

Berg et al. (2023) assumes further linkages and factors determining the trend of each GDP expenditure. components. Because of the high volatility of the Philippines data, we do not assume further link among the trend variables.

The share on potential nominal GDP is used here to ensure that all gaps exhibit the same unit of measure, i.e. percentage deviation from potential.

The specification of the UIP premium is consistent with that in Basu et al. (2020 , 2023 ) and Adrian et al. (2021 ), though it is more general in one respect. In the IPF papers, it is the stock of NFA that determines the UIP premium. In FINEX, the UIP premium depends both on the size of portfolio flows and, through their effect on investors’ required rate of return, on the stock of public debt, the NFA position, and reserves. This hybrid formulation captures both effects and thus fits the data better and lends itself to producing plausible forecasts.

Eq.40 reflects both (i) a demand curve (setting aside net exports which is reflected in eq. 39) as an implicit function of the policy interest rate and the exchange rate, as well as a (ii) supply function primarily focused on the (endogenous) capital flows captured (by and large) in the n f p t r a t term which allows discussing UIP premium and investors tying premium to exogenous risk-on-off idiosyncratic term and a state-contingent component related to public debt (to GDP), reserves and private NFA.

Per the IPF (2023), FX interventions are advisable when shocks are large, leading to significant premium deviations that pose risks to central bank objectives, provided FX interventions effectively support these goals. Interventions must avoid disrupting market efficiency or appearing to target exchange rate levels. However, the model does not account for sterilization costs associated with acquiring and holding FX assets.

The FXI decision are often made at higher frequency indicators (e.g., daily), which come under the purview of FX operations teams and not the team supporting macro-financial policy advice using quarterly models to senior management. The PAMPh2.0, capturing the best fit to the macroeconomic data and historical policy decision, guides policy makers in term of principles for the use of FXI and it also ensures consistency between high-frequency FXI decision making and lower-frequency macro-financial modeling in quarterly quantitative frameworks in central banks.

In PAMPh, the accumulation of domestic bonds by domestic households is not explicitly depicted as in DSGE models. Consequently, the concept of Ricardian equivalence, which hinges on the assumption that individuals anticipate future tax liabilities and adjust their consumption accordingly, does not influence the determination of fiscal multipliers. However, the potency of the fiscal multiplier is contingent upon the vigor of the income channel, as encapsulated in eq.4 by the coefficients a 6 , a 9 and a 10 .

The government current expenditures and the government consumption from the SNA are not equivalent. The former only encompasses expenditures of the central government, whereas the latter takes into account both central and local governments.

The foreign interest rate cost is computed in a similar way.

A value of zero implies that it is equal to its initial steady state value along the Balanced Growth Path (BGP).

In this simulation, we assume that the real price of food gap increases by 10 percentage points in the first two quarters of 2024 compared to the baseline scenario.

The additional increase in consumption is modeled by shocking the residual term of the consumption gap equation.

In 2023, the public debt level stood at the threshold of 60 percent of GDP, significantly surpassing the pre-pandemic average of 40 percent of GDP.

We assume that asset prices are subjected to an exogenous shock (as described in eq.30), resulting in a 10 percent permanent deviation from the baseline level.

The simulation involving FXI assumes that the central bank responds to disorderly market conditions and the rise in the risk premium ( IMF 2023a ). Under this intervention policy, once the shock dissipates, BSP initiates the replenishment of FX reserves to restore them to an adequate level.

For a critical description of the calibration process see Maehle et al. (2021) , and Berg et al. (2023 ) Box 5.

The COVID-19 shock was interpreted as a negative level shift, temporarily increasing the volatility of the GDP trend. However, after 2020, the estimated trends have returned to the pre-pandemic smoothed dynamic.

The Bayesian estimation is adept at efficiently estimating structural coefficients using observed time series data and prior assumptions, maximizing the historical likelihood of the model (i.e., the fit to the data given the model’s structural characteristics). However, a key challenge of this method lies in setting prior distribution assumptions. The choice and configuration of the prior distribution function significantly influence the estimation outcome.

In the following subsection, we detail the most recent estimation of the model and discuss its implications.

In our estimation, we were unable to isolate the direct effects of CPI-related tax changes.

The Reserve Board utilizes the Estimated Dynamic Optimization (EDO) model as a benchmark for forecasting and policy analysis. Inspired by the methodology outlined by Smets and Wouters (2007), the EDO model incorporates additional disaggregation of U.S. domestic spending, particularly in the housing and durable goods sectors. Moreover, the production block is structured to encompass two sectors, distinguishing between faster- and slower-growing industries ( Chung et al., 2010 ).

In-sample simulations are model-based and utilize data up to the beginning of each simulation, excluding external outlooks. In this way, these simulations replicate to a large extent forecasting methods used by central banks.

Only structural shocks are subject to zero means and no autocorrelation requirements. Shocks in non-structural equations, such as equations for trends, may naturally experience autocorrelated shocks by nature.

In the case of core inflation, we calculate its target based on the headline target and changes in the relative price trend of core inflation.

Part of the increase in debt can be attributed to the significant drop in nominal GDP.

Other IMF Content

  • FINEX - A New Workhorse Model for Macroeconomic Forecasting and Policy Analysis
  • A Macro-Model Approach to Monetary Policy Analysis and Forecasting for Vietnam
  • Forecasting and Monetary Policy Analysis in Low-Income Countries: Food and non-Food Inflation in Kenya
  • Part III: Inflation-Forecast Targeting in Four Countries
  • Monetary Policy Analysis Using the Quarterly Projections Model
  • A Model for Monetary Policy Analysis in Uruguay
  • Quarterly Projection Model for Vietnam: A Hybrid Approach for Monetary Policy Implementation
  • Monetary Policy Analysis and Forecasting in the World Economy: A Panel Unobserved Components Approach
  • A Simple Macrofiscal Model for Policy Analysis: An Application to Cambodia
  • An Extended Quarterly Projection Model: Credit Cycle, Macrofinancial Linkages and Macroprudential Measures: The Case of the Philippines

Other Publishers

Asian development bank.

  • Technical and Vocational Education and Training in the Philippines in the Age of Industry 4.0
  • The Distributional Impacts of Fiscal Policy: The Case of the Philippines
  • Disaster Resilience in Asia-A Special Supplement 0f Asia's Journey to Prosperity: Policy, Market, and Technology Over 50 Years
  • ADB Economics Working Paper Series No. 573: Quarterly Forecasting Model for India's Economic Growth, Bayesian Vector Autoregression Approach
  • Gig Economy Employment during the Pandemic: An Analysis of GrabFood Driver Experiences in the Philippines
  • COVID-19 Lockdown Policy and Heterogeneous Responses of Urban Mobility: Evidence from the Philippines
  • Cost-Benefit Analysis of Face-to-Face Closure of Schools to Control COVID-19 in the Philippines
  • Monetary Policy Transmission Mechanism of Bangladesh
  • Measuring Progress on Women's Financial Inclusion and Entrepreneurship in the Philippines: Results from a Micro, Small, and Medium-Sized Enterprise Survey
  • Accessibility Analysis of the South Commuter Railway Project of the Philippines

Inter-American Development Bank

  • MIDAS Modeling for Core Inflation Forecasting
  • Evaluation of Inflation Forecasting Models in Guatemala
  • Does Easing Monetary Policy Increase Financial Instability?
  • Tight Money-Tight Credit: Coordination Failure in the Conduct of Monetary and Financial Policies
  • Integrated Template for Debt Sustainability Analysis: Version 2.0, Instruction Manual, Revised Version
  • Modeling Public Policies in Latin America and the Caribbean
  • Forecasting Inflation in Argentina
  • Credit Risks and Monetary Policy within Caribbean Economies
  • Central Bank Liquidity Management and "Unconventional" Monetary Policies

Nordic Council of Ministers

  • Nordic low CO2 emission scenarios - implemented in the GAINS model: Potential impacts on air pollution following Nordic low greenhouse gas emission initiatives. Scenario analysis performed with the GAINS model

The World Bank

  • Portraits of Labor Market Exclusion 2.0: Country Policy Paper for Bulgaria
  • Portraits of Labor Marker Exclusion 2.0: Country Policy Paper for Poland
  • Portraits of Labor Market Exclusion 2.0: Country Policy Paper for Hungary
  • Portraits of Labor Market Exclusion 2.0: Country Policy Paper for Romania
  • Portraits of Labor Market Exclusion 2.0: Country Policy Paper for Croatia
  • Portraits of Labor Market Exclusion 2.0: Country Policy Paper for Greece
  • What a Waste 2.0: A Global Snapshot of Solid Waste Management to 2050
  • Republic of Indonesia Financial Sector Assessment Program: Monetary Policy.
  • Forecasting Local Climate for Policy Analysis: A Pilot Application for Ethiopia
  • Philippines Economic Update, April 2018: Investing in the Future.
  • Share on facebook Share on linkedin Share on twitter

Cover IMF Working Papers

Table of Contents

  • 4.2 Calibration and Empirical Validation of the Model42
  • View raw image
  • Download Powerpoint Slide

fiscal policy essay

International Monetary Fund Copyright © 2010-2021. All Rights Reserved.

fiscal policy essay

  • [185.66.14.133]
  • 185.66.14.133

Character limit 500 /500

More From Forbes

Fiscal policy and main street: trouble.

  • Share to Facebook
  • Share to Twitter
  • Share to Linkedin

In simple terms, fiscal policy is about government (especially federal) spending, tax policy, and government financing (deficits). With a presidential election on tap, small business owners will pay particular attention to proposals for tax policy. In any poll about small business issues, taxes always float toward the top. Every month NFIB asks a sample of its member firms to identify from a list of 10 items (including “fill in the blank”) their single most important problem. Chart 1 shows the outcome of the voting for taxes and for government regulation (the cost of compliance and lost revenues is a “tax”).

Single Most Important Business Problem: Government Regulations and Taxes. NFIB Small Business ... [+] Economic Trends.

Since 2022, inflation and labor quality have fought it out for the number one problem spot. The price level (CPI) has risen 20% (cumulative) since 2020, destroying the value of savings accounts (every dollar buys less) and wiping out wage gains, leaving real wages down 2% between 2020 to 2023. That’s a tax! An investment project that costs $1,000 in 2020 now costs $1,200 and must be financed at interest rates double those in 2020. Funds set aside to cover depreciation are also reduced in value.

Chart 2 suggests that it takes a slowdown or recession to stop inflation, and possibly reduce prices. This would increase/restore the purchasing power of money, saved and earned. The Federal Reserve’s policies are focused on reducing spending, but with interest rates as the main policy tool, the adjustment falls heavily on interest-sensitive sectors like housing and construction, not on services spending. Congress holds the key to government spending, the major cause of the recent inflation.

Single Most Important Business Problem: Inflation, Taxes, Government Regulations. NFIB Small ... [+] Business Economic Trends.

The cost of complying with government regulations is a perpetual problem. The current administration is pushing to finalize thousands of new rules before the election. The cost of complying will be passed on in higher prices for goods and services. The Office of Management and Budget (OMB) estimates the price of existing regulations at approximately $300 billion annually. All paid for through the prices we pay for goods and services.

New Password Hacking Warning For Gmail, Facebook And Amazon Users

Trump vs. harris 2024 polls: harris’ lead grows—winning by 5 points in one survey, samsung slashes galaxy s24 price ahead of iphone 16 release.

All of this is up in the air now, pending the election in November. A new Congress will deal with taxes and new agency heads will be appointed to write regulations. Courts will deal with disagreements and the Fed will deal with the inflation. And small businesses will continue to be the core of the U.S. economy.

William Dunkelberg

  • Editorial Standards
  • Reprints & Permissions

Join The Conversation

One Community. Many Voices. Create a free account to share your thoughts. 

Forbes Community Guidelines

Our community is about connecting people through open and thoughtful conversations. We want our readers to share their views and exchange ideas and facts in a safe space.

In order to do so, please follow the posting rules in our site's  Terms of Service.   We've summarized some of those key rules below. Simply put, keep it civil.

Your post will be rejected if we notice that it seems to contain:

  • False or intentionally out-of-context or misleading information
  • Insults, profanity, incoherent, obscene or inflammatory language or threats of any kind
  • Attacks on the identity of other commenters or the article's author
  • Content that otherwise violates our site's  terms.

User accounts will be blocked if we notice or believe that users are engaged in:

  • Continuous attempts to re-post comments that have been previously moderated/rejected
  • Racist, sexist, homophobic or other discriminatory comments
  • Attempts or tactics that put the site security at risk
  • Actions that otherwise violate our site's  terms.

So, how can you be a power user?

  • Stay on topic and share your insights
  • Feel free to be clear and thoughtful to get your point across
  • ‘Like’ or ‘Dislike’ to show your point of view.
  • Protect your community.
  • Use the report tool to alert us when someone breaks the rules.

Thanks for reading our community guidelines. Please read the full list of posting rules found in our site's  Terms of Service.

Essay on Fiscal Policy of India

fiscal policy essay

In this essay we will discuss about Fiscal Policy in India. After reading this essay you will learn about: 1. Definition of Fiscal Policy 2. Objectives of Fiscal Policy 3. Role 4. Techniques 5. Merits 6. Shortcomings 7. Suggestions 8. Measures.

  • Essay on the Measures of Fiscal Policy Reforms

Essay # 1. Definition of Fiscal Policy :

Fiscal policy is playing an important role on the economic and social front of a country. Traditionally, fiscal policy in concerned with the determination of state income and expenditure policy. But with the passage of time, the importance of fiscal policy has been increasing continuously for attaining rapid economic growth.

ADVERTISEMENTS:

Accordingly, it has included public borrowing’ and deficit financing as a part of fiscal policy of the country. An effective fiscal policy is composed of policy decisions relating to entire financial structure of the government including tax revenue, public expenditures, loans, transfers, debt management, budgetary deficit, etc.

The policy also tries to attain proper balance between these aforesaid units so as to achieve the best possible results in terms of economic goals. Harvey and Joanson, M., defined fiscal policy as “changes in government expenditure and taxation designed to influence the pattern and level of activity.”

According to G.K. Shaw, “We define fiscal policy to include any design to change the price level, composition or timing of government expenditure or to vary the burden, structure or frequency of the tax payment.” Otto Eckstein defined fiscal policy as “changes in taxes and expenditure which aim at short run goals of full employment price level and stability.”

Essay # 2. Objectives of Fiscal Policy :

In India, the fiscal policy is gaining its importance in recent years with the growing involvement of the government in developmental activities of the country.

Following are some of the important objectives of fiscal policy adopted by the Government of India:

1. To mobilise adequate resources for financing various programmes and projects adopted for economic development.

2. To raise the rate of savings and investment for increasing the rate of capital formation;

3. To promote necessary development in the private sector through fiscal incentive;

4. To arrange an optimum utilisation of resources;

5. To control the inflationary pressures in economy in order to attain economic stability;

6. To remove poverty and unemployment;

7. To attain the growth of public sector for attaining the objective of socialistic pattern of society;

8. To reduce regional disparities; and

9. To reduce the degree of inequality in the distribution of income and wealth.

In order to attain all these aforesaid objectives, the Government of India has been formulating its fiscal policy incorporating the revenue, expenditure and public debt components in a comprehensive manner.

Essay # 3. Role of Fiscal Policy in Economic Development :

One of the important goals of fiscal policy formulated by the Government of India is to attain rapid economic development of the country.

To attain such economic development in the country, the fiscal policy of the country has adopted following two objectives:

1. To raise the rate of productive investment of both public and private sector of the country.

2. To enhance the marginal and average rates of savings for mobilising adequate financial resources for making .investment in public and private sectors of the economy.

The fiscal policy of the country is trying to attain both these two objectives during the plan periods.

Essay # 4. Techniques of Fiscal Policy:

Following are the four important techniques of fiscal policy of India:

(i) Policy of Taxation of Government of India:

One of the important sources of revenue of the Government of India is the tax revenue. Both the direct and indirect taxes are being levied by the Government of India. Direct taxes are progressive by nature and most of indirect taxes are regressive in nature. Taxation plays an important role in mobilising resources for plan.

During the First, Second and Third Plan, additional taxation alone contributed nearly 12.7 per cent, 22.8 per cent and 34 per cent of public sector plan expenditure respectively. The shares during the Fourth, Fifth, Sixth and Seventh Plan were 27 per cent, 37 per cent 22 per cent and 15 per cent respectively.

Total tax revenue collected by the Government of India stands at 72.13 per cent of the total revenue of the Government. Mobilisation of taxes by the Government stands around 15 to 16 per cent of the national income of the country during recent years.

Main objectives of taxation policy in India includes:

(a) Mobilisation of resources for financing economic development;

(b) Formation of capital by promoting saving and investment through time deposits, investment in government bonds, in units, insurance etc.;

(c) Attainment of equality in the distribution of income and wealth through the imposition of progressive direct taxes; and

(d) Attainment of price stability by adopting anti-inflationary taxation policy.

(ii) Public Expenditure Policy of Government of India:

Public expenditure is playing an important role in the economic development of a country like India. With increase in responsibilities of the government and with the increasing participation of government in economic activities of the country, the volume of public expenditure in a highly populated country like India is increasing at a galloping rate. In 1992-93, the public expenditure as percentage of GDP was around 30 per cent.

Public expenditure is of two different types, i.e., developmental and non-developmental expenditure. Developmental expenditure of the Government is mostly related to the developmental activities viz., development of infrastructure, industry, health facilities, educational institutions etc.

The non-developmental expenditure is mostly a maintenance type of expenditure and which is related to maintenance of law and order, defence, administrative services etc. The public expenditure incurred by the Government of India has been creating a serious impact on the production and distribution pattern of the economy.

Following are some of the important features of the policy of public expenditure formulated by the Government of India:

(a) Development of infrastructure:

Development of infrastructural facilities which include development of power projects, railways, road, transportation system, bridges, dams, irrigation projects, hospitals, educational institutions etc. involves huge expenditure by the Government as private investors are very much reluctant to invest in these areas considering the low rate of profitability and high risk involved in it.

(b) Development of public enterprises:

Development of heavy and basic industries are very important for the development of underdeveloped country. But the establishment of these industries involves huge investment and a considerable proportion of risk. Naturally private sector cannot take the responsibility to develop these industries.

Development of these industries has become a responsibility of the Government of India particularly since the introduction of Industrial Policy, 1956. A significant portion of public expenditure has been utilised for the establishment and improvement of these public enterprises.

(c) Support to Private Sector:

Providing necessary support to the private sector for the establishment of industry and other projects is another important objective of public expenditure policy formulated by the Government of India.

(d) Social Welfare and Employment Programmes:

Another important feature of public expenditure policy pursued by the Government of India is its growing involvement in attaining various social welfare programmes and also on employment generation programmes.

(iii) Policy of Deficit Financing of Government of India:

Following the policy of deficit financing as introduced by J.M. Keynes, the Government of India has been adopting the policy for financing its developmental plans since its inception. The deficit financing in India indicates taking loan by the Government from the Reserve Bank of India in the form of issuing fresh dose of currency.

Considering the low level of income, low rate of savings and capital formation, the Government is taking recourse to deficit financing in increasing proportion. Deficit financing is a kind of forced savings.

Accordingly, Dr. V.K.R.V. Rao observed, “Deficit financing is the name of volume of those forced savings which are the result of increase in prices during the period of the government investment. Thus deficit financing helps the country by providing necessary funds for meeting the requirements of economic growth but at the same time it also create the problem of inflationary rise in prices. Thus the deficit financing must be kept within the manageable limit.”

During the First, Second, Third and Fourth Plan deficit financing as percentage of total plan resources was to the extent of 17 per cent, 20 per cent, 13 per cent and 13.5 per cent respectively. But due to adverse consequence of deficit financing through inflationary rise in price level, the extent of deficit financing was reduced to only 3 per cent during the Fifth Plan.

But due to resource constraint, the extent of deficit financing again rose to 14 per cent and 16 per cent of total plan resources respectively.

Thus knowing fully the evils of deficit financing, planners are still maintaining a high rate of deficit financing in the absence of increased tax revenue due to large scale tax evasion and negative contribution of public enterprises. But considering the present inflationary trend in prices, the Government should give lesser stress on deficit financing.

(iv) Public Debt Policy of the Government of India:

As the taxation has got its limit in a poor country like India due to poor taxable capacity of the people, thus the Government is taking recourse to public debt for financing its developmental expenditure. In the post-independence period, the Central Government has been raising a good amount of public debt regularly in order to mobilise a huge amount of resources for meeting its developmental expenditure. Total public debt of the Central Government includes internal debt and external debt.

Internal Debt:

Internal debt indicates the amount of loan raised, by the Government from within the country. The Government raises internal public debt from the open market by issuing bonds and cash certificates and 15 years annuity certificates. The Government also borrows for a temporary period from RBI (treasury bills issued by RBI) and also from commercial banks.

External Debt:

As the internal debt is insufficient thus the Government is also collecting loan from external sources, i.e., from abroad, in the form of foreign capital, technical knowhow and capital goods. Accordingly, the Central Government is also borrowing from international financing agencies for financing various developmental projects.

These agencies include World Bank, IMF, IDA, IFC etc. Moreover, the Government is also collecting inter-governmental loans from various developed countries of the world for financing its various infrastructural projects.

The volume of public debt in India increased at a considerable rate i.e. from Rs 204 crore during the First Plan to Rs 2,135 crore during the Fourth Plan and then to Rs 1,03,226 crore during the Seventh Plan. During the Eighth Plan, the volume of internal debt of the Central Government was amounted to Rs 1,59,972 crore and that of external debt was to the extent of Rs 2,454 crore.

At the end of the second year of the Twelfth Plan, i.e., in 2013-14, total outstanding loan (liabilities) of the Central Government stood at Rs 55,87,000 crore.

Essay # 5. Merits or Advantages of Fiscal Policy of India :

Following are some of the important merits or advantages of fiscal policy of Government of India:

(i) Capital Formation:

Fiscal policy of the country has been playing an important role in raising the rate of capital formation in the country both in its public and private sectors. The gross domestic capital formation as per cent of GDP in India increased from 8.4 per cent in 1950-51 to 19.9 per cent in 1980-81 and then to 39.1 per cent in 2007-08. Therefore, it has created a favourable impact on the public and private sector investment of the country.

(ii) Mobilisation of Resources:

Fiscal policy of the country has been helping to mobilise considerable amount of resources through taxation, public debt etc. for financing its various developmental projects. The extent of internal resource mobilisation for financing plan increased considerably from 70 per cent in 1965- 66 to around 90 per cent in 1997-98.

(iii) Incentives to Savings:

The fiscal policy of the country has been providing various incentives to raise the savings rate both in household and corporate sector through various budgetary policy changes, viz., tax exemption, tax concession etc. The saving rate increased from a mere 8.6 per cent in 1950-51 to 37.7 per cent in 2007-08.

(iv) Inducement to Private Sector:

Private sector of the country has been getting necessary inducement from the fiscal policy .of the country to expand its activities. Tax concessions, tax exemptions, subsidies etc. incorporated in the budgets have been providing adequate incentives to the private sector units engaged in industry, infrastructure and export sector of the country.

(v) Reduction of Inequality:

Fiscal policy of the country has been making constant endeavour to reduce the inequality in the distribution of income and wealth. Progressive taxes on income and wealth tax exemption, subsidies, grant etc. are making a consolidated effort to reduce such inequality. Moreover, the fiscal policy is also trying to reduce the regional disparities through its various budgetary policies.

(vi) Export Promotion:

The Fiscal policy of the Government has been making constant endeavour to promote export through its various budgetary policy in the form of concessions, subsidies etc. As a result, the growth rate of export has increased from a mere 4.6 per cent in 1960-61 to 10.4 per cent in 1996-97.

(vii) Alleviation of Poverty and Unemployment:

Another important merit of Indian fiscal policy is that it is making constant effort to alleviate poverty and unemployment problem through its various poverty eradication and employment generation programmes, like, IRDP, JRY, PMRY, SJSRY, EAS, NREGA etc.

Essay # 6. Shortcomings of Fiscal Policy in India :

Following are the major shortcomings of the fiscal policy of the country:

(i) Instability:

Fiscal policy of the country has failed to attain stability on various fronts. Growing volume of deficit financing has created the problem of inflationary rise in price level. Disequilibrium in its balance of payments has also affected the external stability of the country.

(ii) Defective Tax Structure:

Fiscal policy has also failed to provide a suitable tax structure for the country. Tax structure has failed to raise the productivity of direct taxes and the country has been relying much on indirect taxes. Therefore, the tax structure has become burdensome to the poor.

(iii) Inflation:

Fiscal policy of the country has failed to contain the inflationary rise in price level. Increasing volume of public expenditure on non-developmental heads and deficit financing has resulted in demand-pull inflation. Higher rate of indirect taxation has also resulted in cost-push inflation. Moreover, the direct taxes has failed to check the growth of black money which is again aggravating the inflationary spiral in the level of prices.

(iv) Negative Return of the Public Sector:

The negative return on capital invested in the public sector units has become a serious problem for the Government of India. In-spite of having a huge total investment to the extent of Rs 4,21,089 crore in 2007 on PSUs the return on investment has remained mostly negative or lower. In order to maintain those PSUs, the Government has to keep huge amount of budgetary provisions, thereby creating a huge drainage of scarce resources of the country.

(v) Growing Inequality:

Fiscal policy of the country has failed to contain the growing inequality in the distribution of income and wealth throughout the country. Growing trend of tax evasion has made the tax machinery ineffective for the purpose. Growing reliance on indirect taxes has made the tax structure regressive.

Essay # 7. Suggestions for Necessary Reforms in Fiscal Policy:

Following are some of the important measures suggested for necessary reforms of the fiscal policy of the country:

(i) Progressive Taxes:

The tax structure of the country should try to infuse more progressive elements so that it can put heavy burden on the rich and less burden on the poor. Necessary amendments should be made in respect of irrigation tax, sales tax, excise duty, land revenue, property taxes etc.

(ii) Agricultural Taxation:

The tax net of the country should be extended to the agricultural sector for rapping a huge amount of revenue from the rich agriculturists.

(iii) Broad-based Tax Net:

Tax net of the country should be broad-based so that it can cover increasing number of population having the taxable capacity.

(iv) Checking Tax Evasion:

Adequate measures be taken to check the problem of tax evasion in the country. Tax laws should be made stricter for prosecuting the tax evaders. Tax machinery should be made more efficient and honest to gear up its operations. Tax rate should be reduced to encourage the growing trend of tax compliance.

(v) Increasing Reliance on Direct Taxes:

Tax machinery of the country should attach much more reliance on direct taxes instead of indirect taxes. Accordingly, the tax machinery should try to introduce wealth tax, estate duty, gift tax, expenditure tax etc.

(vi) Simplified Tax Structure:

Tax structure and rules of the country should be simplified so that it can encourage tax compliance among the people and it can remove the unnecessary harassment of the tax payers.

(vii) Reduction of Non-Development Expenditure:

The fiscal policy of the country should try to reduce the non-developmental expenditure of the country. This would reduce the volume of unproductive expenditure and can reduce the inflationary impact of such expenditure.

(viii) Checking Black Money:

The fiscal policy of the country should try to check the problem of black money. In this direction schemes like VDIS should be repeated. Tax rates should be reduced. Corruption and political interference should be abolished. Smuggling and other nefarious activities should be checked.

(ix) Raising the Profitability of PSUs:

The Government should try to restructure its policy on public sector enterprises so that its efficiency and rate of return on capital invested can be raised effectively. PSUs should be managed in rational manner with least government interference and on commercial lines. Accordingly, the policy of budgetary provisions for maintaining the PSUs should gradually be eliminated.

Essay # 8. Measures of Fiscal Policy Reforms:

The Government of India has introduced several fiscal policy reforms which constitute the main basis of the stabilisation policy of the country.

Following are some of the important measures of fiscal policy reforms adopted by the Government of India in recent years:

(i) Reduction of Rates of Direct Taxes:

The peak rate of income tax was reduced to 30 per cent in 1997-98 budget. This has resulted in an increase in the share of direct taxes in total revenue of the country from 19 per cent in 1990-91 to around 61 per cent in 2008-09.

(ii) Simplification of Tax Procedure:

In recent years as per the recommendation of Raja Chelliah or Taxation Reform Committee, several steps have been taken to simplify the tax procedure in the successive budgets. The 1998-99 budget has introduced a series of tax simplification measures, viz., “Saral”, “Samadhan” and “Samman”, which is considered as an important step in right direction.

(iii) Reforms in Indirect Taxes:

These reforms include introduction of advalorem rates, MODVAT scheme etc.

(iv) Fall in the volume of Government Expenditure:

Several measures were undertaken recently by the government. Accordingly, total expenditure of the Government under various heads has been reduced. As a result, total public expenditure as per cent of GDP has declined from 19.7 per cent of GDP in 1990-91 to 16.9 per cent in 2008-09.

(v) Reduction in the Volume of Subsidies:

Central Government has been making huge payments in the form of subsidies, i.e., food subsidies, fertiliser subsidies, export subsidies etc. Steps have been taken to reduce these subsidies in a phased manner.

(vi) Reduction in Fiscal Deficit:

The Central Government has been trying seriously to contain the fiscal deficit in its annual budget. Accordingly, it has reduced the extent of fiscal deficit from 7.7 per cent of GDP in 1990-91 to 6.1 per cent in 2008-09. But fiscal stabilisation necessitates containing the fiscal deficit at least to 3 per cent of GDP.

(vii) Reduction in Public Debt:

Recently, the Central Government has been trying to reduce the burden of public debt. Accordingly, the external debt as per cent of GDP which was 5.4 per cent in 1990-91 gradually declined to 4.9 per cent in 2008-09. The internal debt as per cent of GDP has declined from 48.6 per cent in 1990-91 to 37.9 per cent in 2008-09.

Similarly, the total outstanding loan or liabilities as per cent of GDP also declined from 63.0 per cent in 2003-04 to 58.9 per cent in 2008-09.

(viii) Disinvestment in Public Sector:

Another important fiscal policy reforms introduced by the Government of India is to disinvest the shares of the public sector enterprises. The government has disinvested as part of its stake in 39 selected PSUs since the disinvestment process began in 1992. Till 2006-07, it has raised around Rs 51,608 crore through disinvestment of share of PSUs.

In the mean time, the Government has constituted a Disinvestment Commission to advise it on how to go about disinvesting the shares of PSUs. The Commission, in its first three reports has given its recommendations on 15 PSUs out of 50 referred to it.

The Commission submitted at least eight reports covering 43 PSUs and also undertook diagnostic studies in 1998-99 in respect of these undertakings for giving recommendations.

Related Articles:

  • Monetary Policy and Fiscal Policy of India
  • Crucial Role of Fiscal Policy in an Under-Developed Economy
  • Use of Fiscal Policy for Economic Development (4 Methods)
  • Fiscal Policy for Stabilization | Economics

COMMENTS

  1. Fiscal Policy, Essay Example

    Fiscal Policy, Essay Example. HIRE A WRITER! You are free to use it as an inspiration or a source for your own work. Fiscal policy is basically noted as the procedural policies that are imposed by the government to make sure that the national budget is used for the needs and demands of the public. It also constitutes how the government is able ...

  2. Fiscal Policy: Taking and Giving Away

    Fiscal policy that increases aggregate demand directly through an increase in government spending is typically called expansionary or "loose.". By contrast, fiscal policy is often considered contractionary or "tight" if it reduces demand via lower spending. Besides providing goods and services like public safety, highways, or primary ...

  3. Fiscal Policy Essay

    Essay on Fiscal Policy. Fiscal Policy can be explained in many ways, for example. Fiscal policy is the use of the government budget to affect an economy. When the government decides on the taxes that it collects, the transfer payments it gives out, or the goods and services that it purchases, it is engaging in fiscal policy. The primary ...

  4. Fiscal Policy

    The purpose of Fiscal Policy. Stimulate economic growth in a period of a recession. Keep inflation low (the UK government has a target of 2%) Fiscal policy aims to stabilise economic growth, avoiding a boom and bust economic cycle. Fiscal policy is often used in conjunction with monetary policy.

  5. Essay on Fiscal Policy

    Fiscal Policy can be explained in many ways, for example. Fiscal policy is the use of the government budget to affect an economy. When the government decides on the taxes that it collects, the transfer payments it gives out, or the goods and services that it purchases, it is engaging in fiscal policy. The primary economic impact of any change ...

  6. PDF Essays on Fiscal Policy and Tax Compliance

    ESSAYS ON FISCAL POLICY AND TAX COMPLIANCE By ORONDE DIA SMALL August 2017 Committee Chair: Dr. Sally Wallace Major Department: Economics This dissertation comprises three essays that examine critical aspects of fiscal policy and explores important determinants of tax compliance in a developing country context. The first

  7. Fiscal Policy and Public Financial Management

    This book is a collection of essays dealing with evolving frontiers of research on the subject. Specific themes covered in this book are issues related to direct and indirect taxes, tax evasion, public expenditure and debt, fiscal federalism, fiscal transparency, budget management, environmental federalism, climate change and climate finance ...

  8. IB Economics

    Fiscal policy is a key tool in government macroeconomic management, involving the use of government spending and taxation to influence economic activity. Its effectiveness, however, is subject to various factors, including the ability to target specific sectors, its impact on aggregate demand (AD), and its limitations, such as time lags ...

  9. International Spillovers of U.S. Fiscal Challenges

    The results are confirmed by robustness analysis and show that greater U.S. fiscal challenges affect negatively the policy rates in both EMEs and DEs, with a greater impact observed in EMEs. Moreover, a low degree of financial repression is associated with more significant spillover effects from greater U.S. fiscal challenges.

  10. Fiscal Policy in India: Meaning, Objectives, Instruments & Types

    Fiscal Policy in India is the cornerstone of its economic strategy, which steers the country through various phases of growth, development, and challenges.It plays crucial role in shaping the nation's development trajectory, influencing its macroeconomic stability, and addressing socio-economic challenges.

  11. Taming Public Debt in Europe: Outlook, Challenges, and Policy ...

    Public debt ratios in Europe increased significantly in response to the pandemic and energy shocks and have remained higher than before the pandemic in most countries. Going forward, the projected public debt trajectories are broadly flat overall in advanced Europe but have a rising profile in emerging Europe. Government financing needs are still elevated, and the unwinding of quantitative ...

  12. Monetary Policy vs. Fiscal Policy: What's the Difference?

    Expansionary Fiscal Policy: This is commonly done during recessions to encourage people to spend. ... These include white papers, government data, original reporting, and interviews with industry ...

  13. How to start an essay on fiscal policy

    Begin your essay by introducing the topic of fiscal policy. You could start with a general statement about the importance of fiscal policy in managing an economy. For example: "Fiscal policy plays a crucial role in managing a nation's economy, influencing economic growth, employment rates, and the overall financial stability of a country."

  14. ⇉Free Fiscal policy Essay Examples and Topic Ideas on GraduateWay

    Words: 2192 (9 pages) Fiscal policy can be determined as the use of government spending and taxes In order to alter the Gross Domestic Product (GAP). From the macro perspective, the federal budget is a tool that can shift aggregate demand and thereby alter macroeconomic outcomes. Although fiscal policy can be used to pursue any of the economic ...

  15. Fiscal Policy Essay Examples

    Get your free examples of research papers and essays on Fiscal Policy here. Only the A-papers by top-of-the-class students. Learn from the best!

  16. Fiscal Policy Essay

    The effectiveness of Fiscal policy is measured through its macroeconomic objectives of 3-4% Economic growth, a 5-6% NAIRU and a 2-3% Inflation rate. Although, in recent years it has failed to hit any of these objectives and Fiscal Policy has hence been considered to be inefficient.

  17. ᐅ Essays On Fiscal Policy Free Argumentative, Persuasive, Descriptive

    Fiscal Policy essays require a range of skills including understanding, interpretation and analysis, planning, research and writing. To write an effective essay on Fiscal Policy, you need to examine the question, understand its focus and needs, obtain information and evidence through research, then build a clear and organized answer. ...

  18. A Monetary and Financial Policy Analysis and Forecasting Model for the

    The Bangko Sentral ng Pilipinas (BSP) has enhanced its macroeconomic modeling through the Forecasting and Policy Analysis System (FPAS), transitioning from a multi-equation econometric model to a modernized system centered on the Quarterly Projection Model (QPM). In its new version, the Policy Analysis Model for the Philippines (PAMPh2.0) integrates forward-looking projections, endogenous ...

  19. Essay about Fiscal Policy

    Essay about Fiscal Policy. Most people nowadays seem to think that fiscal policy cannot be used to influence economic activity, and they are supported in this view by the majority of professional macroeconomists. Students are taught that output and employment are determined by the demands and supplies of individuals interacting in a gigantic ...

  20. Fiscal Policy And Main Street: Trouble?

    In simple terms, fiscal policy is about government (especially federal) spending, tax policy, and government financing (deficits). With a presidential election on tap, small business owners will ...

  21. Essay on Fiscal Policy of India

    The fiscal policy of the country has been providing various incentives to raise the savings rate both in household and corporate sector through various budgetary policy changes, viz., tax exemption, tax concession etc. The saving rate increased from a mere 8.6 per cent in 1950-51 to 37.7 per cent in 2007-08.

  22. ECON195

    ECON195 - Week 7 - Essay #2 - Fiscal Policy 2. o Explain how each tool may reduce the inflation and how it impacts employment and growth. Compare and contrast the difference in which monetary policy and fiscal policy maintain a stable economy and help promote economic growth and employment.

  23. Economic Policies: What is the Fiscal Policy? Essay

    Fiscal Policy can be explained in many ways, for example. Fiscal policy is the use of the government budget to affect an economy. When the government decides on the taxes that it collects, the transfer payments it gives out, or the goods and services that it purchases, it is engaging in fiscal policy.

  24. Fiscal Policies Essay

    The two main tools in fiscal policy are taxes and expenditure. Fiscal policy is set by the government and parliament and often used a combination with monetary policy, which set by Reserve Bank of Australia as an example. Furthermore, this essay discusses the Australian government fiscal policies during the

  25. Fiscal Policy Essay Example

    Fiscal Policy Essay Example. Better Essays. 1134 Words; 5 Pages; Open Document Analyze This Draft. Open Document Analyze This Draft. Fiscal Policy Essay Example. View Writing Issues. File. Edit. Tools. Settings. Filter Results. 1134 Words. Grammar. Plagiarism Writing

  26. Fiscal Policy Essay

    Essay about Fiscal Policy Fiscal Policy Most people nowadays seem to think that fiscal policy cannot be used to influence economic activity, and they are supported in this view by the majority of professional macroeconomists. Students are taught that output and employment are determined by the demands and supplies of

  27. Fiscal Policy Essay

    Fiscal policy is the use of taxation and government spending for the purposes of stimulating or slowing down growth in an economy. Fiscal policy can be used for expansionary reasons, which is aimed at growing the economy and increasing employment, or contractionary which is intended to slow the growth of an economy.