Analysing the informal sector in South Africa: Knowledge and policy gaps, conceptual and data challenges

  • October 2019
  • In book: Fourie FCvN (ed) 2018. The South African informal sector: creating jobs, reducing poverty
  • Publisher: HSRC Press, Cape Town

Frederick. C.v.N. Fourie at University of the Free State

  • University of the Free State

Discover the world's research

  • 25+ million members
  • 160+ million publication pages
  • 2.3+ billion citations

Supplementary resource (1)

  • Geoffroy Heimlich
  • Clément Mambu Nsangathi

Isaac Khambule

  • Sinhle Thwala

Tyanai Masiya

  • Lungile Tim Mabunda
  • Jean Damascene Mvunabandi

Celumusa Makepeace Chonco

  • Angel Bolosha

Sikhulumile Sinyolo

  • Hector Ramoroka

Kgabo Ramoroka

  • Gabriel Tati
  • Shanaaz Dunn

Pranitha Maharaj

  • Lilian Nwosu

Jonathan Crush

  • Dev South Af

Derek Yu

  • S AFR J ECON

James Heintz

  • REV DEV ECON
  • Ravi Kanbur

Terence Moll

  • Ronald H. Coase

Christian Rogerson

  • Recruit researchers
  • Join for free
  • Login Email Tip: Most researchers use their institutional email address as their ResearchGate login Password Forgot password? Keep me logged in Log in or Continue with Google Welcome back! Please log in. Email · Hint Tip: Most researchers use their institutional email address as their ResearchGate login Password Forgot password? Keep me logged in Log in or Continue with Google No account? Sign up

Creating jobs, reducing poverty I: Why the informal sector should be taken seriously and enabled properly

This is the first in a short series of edited extracts from a new REDI3x3 book: The South African Informal Sector: Creating Jobs, Reducing Poverty . The research findings reported in the book address a significant knowledge gap in economic research and policy analysis.

Download from HSRC Open Access:  

https://www.hsrcpress.ac.za/books/the-south-african-informal-sector-providing-jobs-reducing-poverty

The book flags the importance of explicitly addressing the informal sector in policy initiatives to boost employment and inclusive growth and reduce poverty. Its last chapter – from which the extracts are drawn – generates a synthesis of key findings on the informal sector and develops the outlines of a constructive policy approach.

This first extract presents a compact picture of the size and contribution of the South African informal sector, also highlighting key policy-relevant features. Forthcoming extracts will consider the employment-generating performance of the sector; the barriers and constraints faced by informal enterprises and workers; and a proposed policy approach to strengthen the informal sector and boost its role in job creation, poverty reduction and the provision of livelihoods (including a constructive way to approach possibly ‘formalising’ the informal sector [1] ).

Introduction

It is not uncommon to find researchers and commentators viewing informal-sector participants as being without aspirations or entrepreneurial skills, or as having no meaningful role to play in generating employment or reducing poverty.

The evidence presented in this book shows that the informal sector is a significant component of the economy that provides employment, livelihoods and income for millions of workers and business owners. This has, however, largely been overlooked by economic analysts and policy-makers in South Africa (and elsewhere). The informal sector has remained forgotten or, at best, in the margins of economic analysis and policy consciousness.

The findings on employment creation as well as enterprise entry suggest that the lack of attention paid to this segment of the economy is a significant oversight and a missed opportunity. This relates to its employment potential as well as its role in inclusive growth and poverty reduction.

The significance of the South African informal sector: A compact picture

It is crucial to analyse the informal sector as an integral (and complex) part of the economy and economic policy. The empirical evidence robustly demonstrates the informal sector’s potential in terms of its contribution to employment, but also to poverty reduction and the economy as a whole.

* Definition: Informal enterprises are enterprises, with or without employees, that are not incorporated and not registered for taxation. The informal sector comprises all informal enterprises, their owner-operators/employers and all employees, paid and unpaid, in all economic sectors. (For more on this, see the Appendix below). [2]

The informal sector mostly comprises very small enterprises (frequently fewer than five individuals) that often are based in poor neighbourhoods and generates quite low earnings for enterprises and individuals. In terms of gross domestic output, the informal sector is estimated to contribute about 6% to GDP (gross domestic product) (2013 data; Stats SA 2014: 9). [3]

Still, these are economic activities that put income in the hands of millions of people. Supporting and strengthening these activities holds the potential to inject resources into poorer households and areas and should be a central part of broad economic empowerment and the pursuit of inclusive growth.

Employment in the informal sector

GDP is only one measure of contribution. Across the country the informal sector in South Africa is a significant source of employment. Approximately 2.3 million people worked in the non-agricultural informal sector in 2013, a year central to our quantitative analysis. (In 2018 it reached 2.9 million.) At about 17% of total employment, one in every six South Africans who work, work in the informal sector. In the NDP (National Development Plan) the sector (together with domestic work) is projected to generate almost two million new jobs by 2030. The NDP has no specific plans or proposals for the sector, though (see Fourie, Chapter 15 in this volume).

Almost 80% of the approximately 1.4 million informal enterprises are one-person firms (also called own-account workers). Yet about 1.1 million people – about half of the people working in the sector – work in enterprises that have employees (i.e. are multi-person firms). Most of these employing enterprises are in construction, retail trade, and services, but also in manufacturing and communication. The proportion of employing firms has been growing steadily since 2000, as has the propensity to employ. In 2013 the employing firms provided about 850 000 paid jobs for owner-operators and employees. What is striking is that the number of paid jobs in the informal sector (850 000) is almost double the direct employment in the formal mining sector (approximately 450 000 in 2013).

Thus, while the informal sector in South Africa is small compared to other developing countries and also sub-Saharan Africa (see the comparative analysis of Grabrucker et al., Chapter 3 in the book), its role as a source of employment and livelihoods for millions of people must be properly appreciated. Moreover, the sector is not homogeneous or comprising only own-account workers (often assumed to be street traders and hawkers) – various dimensions of heterogeneity characterise the world of informal enterprises and shape its functioning. The annual entry of new enterprises is quite high, as is the number of informal enterprises that grow their employment. There is no shortage of entrepreneurship or desire to grow.

This picture is not intended to romanticise work in the informal sector. Working in and running enterprises in the informal sector is anything but easy. Working hours are long, working conditions are often difficult. Earnings and returns are very low for all but a few. Both the mean and median earnings for the informal sector are less than half that of the formal sector (Rogan and Skinner, Chapter 4 in the book). In 2014 the typical worker in the formal sector earned about R4 300 per month (mean earnings), while the typical informal-sector worker earned only R2 000. Earnings of the self-employed in the informal sector are higher than those of employees, particularly for men (whose average earnings as self-employed workers are more than R6700 per month). [4]

Owners and employees of enterprises across the size spectrum take risks, face many barriers and struggle to be viable, with the likely consequences of failure for the involved households severe. But, compared to being unemployed the informal sector is an important vehicle for gainful employment and earning income. Given the high levels of unemployment and poverty – and the NDP objective of almost 2 million more jobs in the informal sector – the policy goal, at least in the short to medium term, should not be to shrink or eliminate the informal sector, but to grow and strengthen it – to create a larger, more dynamic informal sector with more viable, self-reliant enterprises and additional, better-quality employment. [5] , [6] (Such a growing sector will probably need, and involve, selected elements of ‘smart’ formalisation, as discussed in forthcoming articles in this series.)

The role of the informal sector in poverty reduction

Linked to the role of the sector in job creation is the vital impact of informal-sector employment on poverty alleviation . The work of Cichello and Rogan (see Chapter 9 in the book and their Econ3x3 article ) shows that informal-sector income is relatively effective in reducing poverty. This is because income from informal-sector work mostly flows to households that are poor. In terms of poverty impact, the destruction of 100 jobs in the informal sector is the equivalent of losing about 60 to 80 formal-sector jobs. From a poverty-reduction viewpoint this is a major finding for policy-makers: one cannot be cavalier about losing or destroying informal-sector jobs.

At this point we can already say that the overall policy goal must be to retain existing informal-sector employment (i.e. measures should do no harm), to improve the livelihoods, security and income of those already in the informal sector, and address barriers to entry and growth to create room for newcomers and employment expansion. In short, policy must enable and support enterprises and workers in the informal sector. The informal sector simply is, to borrow a phrase, ‘too big to fail’. Recognising the informal sector as an integral part of the economy, rather than ignoring it, is a crucial first step towards such a policy approach.

Key policy-relevant features of the informal sector

The analysis and findings from the different chapters suggest several factors that could guide the design of effective policies to support and develop the informal sector. They also point to the need for carefully designed and differentiated policies.

The sector is not homogeneous, but is spread across industries

For policy-making, disaggregation by industry is particularly important. The notion of the informal sector disguises significant heterogeneity. It is not a sector in the normal sense of the word, but comprises slices of almost all the industries, or branches of economic activity, in an economy. As is the case with the formal sector, different industries/sectors (or branches of economic activity) have very different constraints to viability and growth and thus different policy needs. Retail and wholesale trade is by far the largest industry in the informal sector. However, its share of enterprises has been declining, from approximately 70% in 2001 to 57% (and 52% of persons) in 2013 (Chapter 5 in the book). Manufacturing displayed a declining share, while construction’s share grew robustly; ‘community and social services’ as well as ‘transport and communication’ also grew substantially. Policy measures should not only be built around trade (which tends to be the policy preoccupation of local authorities in particular). [7] The employment potential of a sector such as construction holds promise: in townships this sector and its craft-based services are less vulnerable to formal-sector competition compared to tradeable [8] products. Construction may also be very responsive to growing income levels and a growing middle class. In addition, housing maintenance and upgrading could play a major role in enhancing the quality of township living environments. Nevertheless, the needs of the trade sector with regard to security of tenure, suitable premises and location, utilities and security remain important – it employs up to half of informal-sector workers. Trade workers are also particularly vulnerable to police harassment.

Gender and the position of women

Changes in trade also highlight changes in the gender composition of the informal sector. The share of women in overall informal-sector employment (including enterprise ownership) declined significantly between 2008 and 2014. While, traditionally, informal trade has been a bigger component of informal-sector employment for women relative to men, much of the overall decline in female informal-sector employment occurred in trade (notably food vendors). A decline in women’s participation in the informal sector is a source of concern, given the importance of money in the hands of women in securing household well-being and the corresponding implications regarding poverty alleviation.

However, Rogan and Skinner (Chapter 4 in the book) also report that, in this period, own-account work became a smaller component of women’s total informal-sector employment, while a larger proportion became paid employees or employers. [9] This signals a significant reconfiguration of the composition of the informal sector : for women, a move away from own-account work towards working in multi-person firms as either employers or employees (amidst a decline in total informal-sector employment for women); for men in multi-person enterprises, a move towards being employers rather than employees. QLFS (Quarterly Labour Force Survey) data also show that more women have moved into managerial positions. This suggests that the position of some women in the informal sector has in fact improved.

Spatial dimensions and townships

There are major differences between provinces and between the metropolitan areas, with rural areas again different. Calculations from recent QLFS data that include all eight metros show that, generally, the share of the workforce that works in the informal sector is

lowest in Gauteng and the Western Cape, highest in the poorer provinces of Limpopo, Mpumalanga, Eastern Cape and KwaZulu-Natal (with the latter two provinces and the Free State showing large decreases in 2008–2013);

higher in non-metropolitan than metropolitan municipalities;

higher for those living in traditional communal areas and in urban informal settlements than in urban or rural formal settlements; and

highest in Mangaung and lowest in Cape Town and Tshwane, with a middle group comprising Johannesburg, eThekwini, Ekurhuleni and Nelson Mandela Bay. [10]

Such patterns and concomitant trends reflect complex social changes related to demography, poverty, unemployment, urbanisation, migrant work and so forth. Generally, it would appear that the higher the poverty level of areas, the higher the proportion of people working in the informal sector.

Clearly, different provinces face different informal-sector policy challenges, as do different metropolitan areas, non-metropolitan cities (secondary cities) and towns. Dealing with small or shrinking informal sectors (amidst high unemployment) may require different policies compared to areas with comparatively large informal sectors, requiring careful analysis of specific factors that constrain entry, viability and employment expansion locally. Thus, it is important that national informal-sector policies allow, enable and support differentiated provincial and local-government policies.

Looking deeper into the situation within township areas, where the informal sector is mostly found, Charman and Petersen (Chapter 10 in the book and their Econ3x3 article ) identified striking spatial patterns in the location of informal enterprises. Using small-area censuses of selected Cape Town townships, they find that informal enterprises are located throughout townships and informal settlements, notably in residential areas rather than in commercial or main-street areas. In these townships, only 24% of informal enterprises are on the ‘high street’, the main thoroughfare and commuter pedestrian area – a broadly consistent pattern. [11] Several business categories have a strong preference for residential areas, for example grocery retailers (spaza shops), take-away food businesses and liquor retail outlets – their primary competitive advantage is their proximity to residential customers. [12]

Understanding the texture, spatial interactions and dynamics of the informal sector in townships is particularly relevant for local government policies. For example, zoning restrictions or permissions (licences) as well as the provision of services and premises must be sensitive to the economic logic of why enterprises have chosen to be located where they are, including local and sector-specific peculiarities, demand and income levels. The study indicates the inappropriateness of simply applying ‘standard’ modernist city planning and zoning approaches in the township context, including restricting businesses in residential areas. At the same time, one must be equally aware that negative externalities could arise in such circumstances due to, for example, noise, crowding and pollution that affect households and other enterprises negatively, both in township and formal business areas. [13]

The finding that a large majority of enterprises are located at owners’ homes may reflect something else, though. It is likely that most of these enterprises are still largely integrated into the household, i.e. in terms of operation, labour and finances they are not differentiated from the family. While this integration may be largely explained by economic, social and family imperatives, it could have important implications for the functioning of the enterprise. The potential significance of the institutional differentiation between household and enterprise (or lack of it) for the developmental status, viability and employment behaviour of informal enterprises is discussed in a forthcoming extract.

The informal sector in the rural economy

The situation of the informal sector in rural towns presents another spatial complexity. A case study by Neves and Du Toit of a rural KwaZulu-Natal town (Chapter 13 in the book) provides many insights (even though the variation between rural towns in likely to be large). A vital question relates to how the town’s economy, and its informal sector in particular, links with surrounding commercial farming activities. The answer is: not much. Modern commercial agriculture largely leapfrogs the local non-farm economy of small towns and deals with corporate suppliers and buyers in large towns and cities, consolidating a significant rural–urban divide. Business activity and employment in a rural town’s informal sector may not be driven by agriculture.

The main inflows of income into many towns are government salaries and welfare grants, in some cases also transport and tourism. The scope for the informal sector (and the town economy) is fundamentally constrained by low incomes, limited demand and limited scope for multipliers to generate additional rounds of spending. The phenomenon of the bustling ‘month-end market’, when social grants and salaries are spent on consumables, presents a vital opportunity for informal-market participants. Yet it indicates unevenness and discontinuity in local spending and thus business activity, both formal and informal.

The policy challenge is to support sectors and activities in the rural economy that can grow or sustain employment (only some of which may involve agriculture). The local agro-food retail sector remains an important candidate. The needs and challenges will vary considerably across farming regions and ecological conditions. Nevertheless, the size and prevalence of existing informal markets in rural towns suggest that the provision of basic infrastructure (e.g. vending sites, storage facilities and basic utilities) could make a significant difference to many in the informal sector. Local government has an important role to play in this respect.

Beyond the towns, a key component of the rural economy is informal-sector agriculture [14] (which is usually omitted from informal-sector analysis due to data and policy conventions). In path-breaking work, despite severe data difficulties, Cousins (Chapter 14 in the book) estimates the size of informal-sector agriculture at 400 000 to 500 000 persons. This adds significantly to the size of the South African informal sector, inclusively defined. Informal-sector farmers frequently suffer from limited funds to finance production inputs.

The markets that they typically supply also are distinctive. Bakkie traders, hawkers and farm-gate buyers constitute valued customers. Transport of produce to town markets is a key constraint. Sales to formal supermarkets are largely ruled out by procurement practices and quality standards (a constraint also faced by informal producers in urban areas, as discussed below). The markets typically supplied by informal-sector farmers are very different from the supermarket-led value chains that are the focus of many interventions to support smallholder agriculture. In designing interventions, informal-sector agriculture must be understood on its own terms. The fortunes of informal-sector farmers are also closely tied to those of traders in small towns. Both groups would benefit from municipalities helping to strengthen informal markets for fresh produce and livestock.

Next extract: The employment-generating potential of the informal sector

The edited extracts are from:

Fourie FCvN (2018) Enabling the forgotten sector: Informal-sector realities, policy approaches and formalisation in South Africa. Chapter 17 in Fourie FCvN (ed) The South African Informal Sector: Creating Jobs, Reducing Poverty. HSRC Press, Cape Town.

Download from HSRC Open Access: https://www.hsrcpress.ac.za/books/the-south-african-informal-sector-providing-jobs-reducing-poverty

Referenced chapters, by number:

1. Analysing the informal sector in South Africa: Knowledge and policy gaps, conceptual and data challenges – Frederick Fourie

3. The informal sector in sub-Saharan Africa: A comparative perspective – Katharina Grabrucker, Michael Grimm & François Roubaud

4. The size and structure of the South African informal sector 2008–2014: A labour-force analysis – Mike Rogan & Caroline Skinner

5. Informal-sector employment in South Africa: An enterprise analysis using the SESE survey – Frederick Fourie

9. Informal-sector employment and poverty reduction in South Africa: The contribution of ‘informal’ sources of income – Paul Cichello & Michael Rogan

10. Informal micro enterprises in a township context: A spatial analysis of business dynamics in five Cape Town localities – Andrew Charman & Leif Petersen

13. Informal-sector employment in the rural non-farm economy in South Africa – David Neves & Andries du Toit

14. Employment in informal-sector agriculture in South Africa – Ben Cousins

15. Evolving policy paradigms: The National Development Plan, employment and the informal sector in South Africa – Frederick Fourie

16. Informal-sector policy and legislation in South Africa: Repression, omission and ambiguity – Caroline Skinner

Other references :

Charman A (2017) Micro-enterprise predicament in township economic development: Evidence from Ivory Park and Tembisa. South African Journal of Economic and Management Sciences 20(1),

ILO (2015) Recommendation concerning the transition from the informal to the formal economy . Recommendation 204. International Labour Conference. Geneva: ILO

Stats SA (Statistics South Africa) (2014) Gross domestic product . Statistical Release P0441. Pretoria: Stats SA

Background on the book and the extracts

When the REDI3x3 project was launched in 2012, the informal sector was identified, in founding and framing documents , as a significant ‘knowledge gap’. A sub-project called ISEP (Informal-sector employment project) was launched in 2013, with the author as convenor and Caroline Skinner of UCT as co-convenor. The multi-disciplinary, data-intensive research and workshop interactions of more than twenty researchers and experts culminated in a 500-page, seventeen-chapter collective work.

The objective of the volume is to provide the groundwork for a more informed, meaningful debate and focused research on evidence-based policy options. Given an era of increased pressure for evidence-based policy-making, the work is strongly evidence- and data-driven, with quantitative contributions combined with qualitative research and case studies. The chapters reflect various methods of analysis to understand a complex phenomenon from a range of paradigmatic, disciplinary and methodological perspectives, often using new data. One aim has been to partly bridge the divides between economics and other disciplines – and, within economics, between labour economists, poverty and development analysts, and macroeconomists.

The definition of the informal sector

A key analytical distinction is that between informal-sector employment and informal employment, and between the informal sector and the informal economy. The potential confusion within these two pairs of concepts is an important one, notably from a policy perspective. In recent South African debates and analysis, one sometimes finds an imprecise use of these two concepts, an indiscriminate mixing of them, or treating them as if they are synonymous.

The formal statistical definitions can become quite technical, also reflecting practical and data collection considerations as well as differences between countries. A good reference point is the deliberations and documents of the ICLS (International Conference of Labour Statisticians), which has set international standards on official labour statistics (see Hussmanns 2003). Stats SA has adopted these standards in its QLFS, but uses a slightly different definition in the SESE. Here it suffices to formulate them in basic conceptual terms, as follows:

  • Informal enterprises: enterprises, with or without employees, that are not incorporated and not registered for taxation. Sometimes the definition is limited to unregistered enterprises that have fewer than five employees (see chapters 4 and 5 in the book).
  • Informal sector: all informal enterprises, their owner-operators/employers and all employees, paid and unpaid, in all economic sectors (manufacturing, retail, etc., including agriculture8). It excludes domestic workers and also subsistence agriculture, which is defined as not producing for the market but rather for own use (see Cousins, Chapter 14 in the book).
  • Informal-sector employment: an enterprise-based concept, comprising those working in the informal sector as either owner-operators/employers or employees, paid and unpaid. Its focus is employment in informal enterprises.
  • Informal employment: an employee-based concept which comprises all employees or workers that do not have formal employment contracts or benefits in both the informal and formal sectors as well as households (see discussion later). Its focus is employment conditions and unprotected work.
  • Informal economy: all forms of informal employment: ‘all economic activi­ties by workers and economic units that are – in law or in practice – not covered or insufficiently covered by formal arrangements’ (ILO 2002: 25).9 Thus, the informal economy comprises all informal-sector employment plus informally employed workers in the formal sector and households. It is premised on the analysis of employment conditions rather than employ­ment opportunities and employment creation.

The broad concept of ‘informal employment’ was adopted by the ILO’s 2003 international labour conference (ILO 2003a, 2003b). The introduction of the broad concept of informal employment has been important in drawing attention to unprotected workers in the informal sector, the formal sector and households. However, it is evidently important to use a definition suited to the research question and the phenomena that are being examined. The two definitions refer to different things and should not be conflated. As noted by Hussmanns (2003: 2) of the ILO Bureau of Statistics:

‘Employment in the informal sector’ and ‘informal employment’ are concepts which refer to different aspects of the ‘informalisation’ of employment and to different targets for policy-making. One of the two concepts cannot replace the other. They are both useful for analytical purposes and, hence, complement each other. However, the two concepts need to be defined and measured in a coherent and consistent manner, so that one can be clearly distinguished from the other. Statistics users and others often tend to confuse the two concepts because they are unaware of the different observation units involved: enterprises on the one hand, and jobs on the other.

Appendix references

Hussmanns R (2003) Statistical definition of informal employment: Guidelines endorsed by the Seventeenth International Conference of Labour Statisticians . Geneva: ILO

ILO (International Labour Organisation) (2002) Resolution concerning decent work and the informal economy . International Labour Conference, 90th Session, International Labour Office, Geneva.

ILO (2003a) The scope of the employment relationship: Report IV . International Labour Conference, 91st Session, International Labour Office, Geneva

ILO (2003b) Guidelines concerning a statistical definition of informal employment. In Report of the conference: Seventeenth International Conference of Labour Statisticians .

[1] The idea of formalising the informal economy has received prominence due to the International Labour Organisation’s International Labour Conference 2014 and 2015 deliberations, resulting in Recommendation 204 concerning ‘the transition from the informal to the formal economy’ (ILO 2015).  

[2] The book is about the informal sector and informal-sector employment (as an enterprise-based concept). Thus it is not about the broader concepts of the informal economy and informal employment (which combine all forms of employment that are not characterised by formalised employment contracts, conditions and benefits such as legal or social protection; these could be in the informal sector but also, notably, in the formal sector and households). It is important to clearly distinguish these concepts, since the potential confusion between them is an important one, notably from a policy perspective (see the Appendix below and Fourie, Chapter 1 in the book).  

[3] The accepted definition of the informal sector excludes illegal business activities like the production and sale of drugs. Approaches that use the concept of the ‘shadow economy’ or ‘underground economy’ often include illegal activities, tax evasion, etc. as well as the informal sector. Such approaches may erroneously suggest that the informal economy is equivalent to the shadow economy and thus overestimate the size of the informal economy/sector significantly.  

[4] Median earnings for male self-employed in the informal sector were about R3 000 per month, but only R2 000 per month for informal-sector male employees (in 2014). Women in the informal sector earned about 70% of men’s earnings, which is similar to the formal-sector ratio. This gender difference is particularly pronounced among the informal self-employed, where women’s median earnings are only 50% of men’s median earnings (i.e. R1 500 and R3 000, respectively, in 2014). See Rogan and Skinner (Chapter 4 in the book) for more earnings data.  

[5] The idea of eliminating the informal sector refers to a phrase used in the 2006 AsgiSA (Accelerated and Shared Growth Initiative for South Africa) policy initiative with regard to the ‘second economy’ (see section 1 of Fourie, Chapter 5 in the book). In the long term, somewhat idealistically, it would be preferable not to have much of an informal sector, but then only as long as there is no significant unemployment.  

[6] As highlighted by Skinner (Chapter 16 in the book), there are numerous cases of actual elimination of informal-sector livelihoods, especially in cities like Johannesburg and Durban.  

[7] For example, in the GIBUS (Gauteng Informal Business Upliftment Strategy) of 2015 the discussion, especially of municipal policies, is almost exclusively about informal traders.  

[8] This term is used to indicate goods and services that can be transported readily and traded in a location distant from the one where it was produced. Goods can have different levels of tradeability, depending on the cost of transportation.  

[9] Still, male owners are more likely to have employees than female owners: being male is associated with a significantly higher propensity to employ (Chapter 5 in the book).

[10] Average share of the informal sector in total employment for 2015 and 2016: Mangaung (almost 19%) and Buffalo City (17%), Cape Town and Tshwane (about 11%), Johannesburg, eThekwini, Ekurhuleni and Nelson Mandela Bay (14%–15%). Also see Rogan and Skinner (Chapter 4 in the book), who used 2014 data.

[11] For two townships in Midrand in Gauteng, Charman (2017: 5, 7) finds that 32% and 34% of enterprises are on the high street – higher than in the Western Cape sites, but still quite low.  

[12] Research on food security in poorer households shows a preference for frequent purchases due to lack of refrigeration as well as irregular income.  

[13] This also applies to informal enterprises in non-residential areas, especially in formal commercial areas in cities as well as towns. In small towns the ‘formal’ business areas may gradually degrade and become informal as informal traders, for example, increasingly occupy pavement areas around formal businesses. Essentially, in policy-making the interests of the informal sector and the formal sector, including formal residential areas, must be harmonised.

[14] Informal-sector agriculture is conceptually distinguished from subsistence agriculture by the farmer regularly selling a substantive amount of output in informal or formal markets. Making the distinction in practice is extremely difficult – in the real world, these analytical distinctions are blurred.

Download article

Post a commentary.

This comment facility is intended for considered commentaries to stimulate substantive debate. Comments may be screened by an editor before they appear online. To comment one must be registered and logged in .

This comment facility is intended for considered commentaries to stimulate substantive debate. Comments may be screened by an editor before they appear online. Please view "Submitting a commentary" for more information.

Editology: Where answers meet curiosity

The Role of the Informal Sector in the Economic Development of Local Areas in South Africa

  • May 21, 2023

role of informal sectors

The informal sector plays a crucial role in the economic development of local areas in South Africa. It encompasses a wide range of economic activities that are not regulated by the government or formalized through official channels. This sector is characterized by its flexibility, low entry barriers, and ability to provide employment opportunities for a significant portion of the population. We will explore the various ways in which the informal sector contributes to the economic development of local areas in South Africa, focusing on the municipalities and their specific challenges and opportunities.

Employment Generation and Poverty Alleviation

The informal sector is a significant source of employment in South Africa, particularly in local areas and municipalities. It provides income-generating opportunities for individuals who are unable to secure formal employment due to various factors such as limited education, lack of skills, or a weak job market. The informal sector helps to alleviate poverty by offering self-employment opportunities and creating jobs for a substantial number of people.

Contribution to GDP and Economic Growth

The informal sector makes a substantial contribution to the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) of South Africa. Although accurate data on the sector’s size and contribution is challenging to obtain due to its informal nature, estimates suggest that it accounts for a significant share of the country’s economic output. In local areas and municipalities, where formal employment opportunities may be limited, the informal sector becomes a vital driver of economic growth and development.

Entrepreneurship and Innovation

The informal sector fosters entrepreneurship and serves as a breeding ground for innovation in local areas of South Africa. Many individuals start small businesses in this sector, utilizing their skills and creativity to identify niche markets and meet local demands. The sector’s flexible nature allows for experimentation and adaptation, leading to the development of new products, services, and business models. These entrepreneurial activities contribute to economic diversification and the overall vibrancy of local economies.

Integration of Marginalized Groups

The informal sector often provides a means for marginalized groups, such as women, youth, and individuals from disadvantaged backgrounds, to participate in economic activities. In South Africa, where historical inequalities persist, the informal sector offers a pathway for these groups to enter the economy and improve their livelihoods. By providing opportunities for economic empowerment, the informal sector helps in reducing social disparities and promoting inclusive growth in local areas and municipalities.

Local Trade and Supply Chains

The informal sector plays a vital role in local trade and supply chains, particularly in rural areas and townships. Informal markets, street vendors, and small-scale enterprises form the backbone of local economies, providing goods and services to the surrounding communities. These businesses create a multiplier effect by supporting upstream and downstream activities, such as sourcing raw materials, transportation, packaging, and distribution. Thus, the informal sector contributes to the overall economic vitality and resilience of local areas.

Tourism and Cultural Heritage

South Africa is known for its rich cultural heritage and diverse tourist attractions. The informal sector plays a crucial role in supporting tourism activities in local areas and municipalities. Informal traders, crafters, and tour guides offer unique experiences to tourists, showcasing local traditions, arts, and crafts. The sector’s contribution to tourism not only generates income but also preserves and promotes cultural heritage, fostering a sense of pride and identity within the local communities.

Challenges and Opportunities for the Informal Sector

While the informal sector presents numerous opportunities for economic development, it also faces significant challenges. Limited access to finance, lack of formal recognition, inadequate infrastructure, and regulatory constraints are some of the key hurdles that informal businesses encounter. Addressing these challenges requires a multi-dimensional approach that involves collaboration between local governments, private sector organizations, and civil society. By recognizing the potential of the informal sector and addressing its challenges, local areas and municipalities in South Africa can harness its full potential for economic development.

To support the growth and development of the informal sector, local governments can implement policies and regulations that facilitate formalization and provide support services tailored to the needs of informal businesses. This includes simplifying registration processes, offering financial assistance and training programs, improving access to markets, and creating a conducive business environment. Collaboration with microfinance institutions and development organizations can also help in providing access to capital and financial services for informal entrepreneurs.

Investments in infrastructure development are crucial for the informal sector to thrive. Improving transportation networks, marketplaces, and basic amenities such as water and sanitation facilities can enhance the productivity and competitiveness of informal businesses. Local governments should also consider spatial planning that integrates the needs of informal activities, creating designated areas or zones where informal businesses can operate without hindrances.

Furthermore, fostering partnerships between formal and informal sectors can unlock synergies and create mutually beneficial relationships. For instance, formal businesses can collaborate with informal suppliers or subcontractors, providing them with access to larger markets and enhancing their capacity. Similarly, formal businesses can benefit from the flexibility, agility, and local knowledge of informal enterprises. These partnerships can contribute to the formalization and upgrading of informal businesses, leading to increased productivity and competitiveness.

Local areas and municipalities can also leverage the potential of the informal sector by promoting entrepreneurship education and skills development programs. By equipping individuals with the necessary knowledge and skills, they can enhance their chances of success in the informal sector. This can be done through vocational training, mentorship programs, and business development initiatives. Additionally, fostering an entrepreneurial culture and mindset within local communities can encourage innovation and self-employment.

In conclusion, the informal sector plays a vital role in the economic development of local areas and municipalities in South Africa. Its contributions range from employment generation and poverty alleviation to entrepreneurship, innovation, and the integration of marginalized groups. By recognizing the potential of the informal sector and addressing its challenges, local areas and municipalities can harness its full potential for economic development. Through supportive policies, infrastructure development, partnerships, and skills development initiatives, the informal sector can thrive, contributing to inclusive growth, poverty reduction, and the overall well-being of local communities in South Africa.

  • # economic contributions of informal sector
  • # economic development through informal sector
  • # economic impact of informal businesses
  • # informal economy development South Africa
  • # informal sector and economic growth
  • # informal sector and local development
  • # informal sector and regional growth
  • # informal sector benefits South Africa
  • # informal sector economic development South Africa
  • # informal sector impact on local areas
  • # informal sector influence on local areas
  • # informal sector role in South Africa
  • # local area development informal sector
  • # local economic development and informal sector
  • # local economic growth informal sector
  • # role of informal businesses South Africa
  • # role of informal sector in local economy
  • # South Africa informal economy
  • # South Africa informal sector contributions
  • # South African informal sector benefits

Ways of Reducing the Effects of Tropical Cyclones

Bibliography of drought and desertification, richie mccaw crash: debunking fake news on social media.

  • Aug 01, 2024

Understanding SASSA Status Check: A Comprehensive Guide

  • Jul 25, 2024

Angie Stylish: The Hot Bedroom Video Trending in Ghana

  • Jul 24, 2024
  • Privacy Policy
  • A-Z Publications

Annual Review of Economics

Volume 12, 2020, review article, informality: causes and consequences for development.

  • Gabriel Ulyssea 1,2,3
  • View Affiliations Hide Affiliations Affiliations: 1 Department of Economics, University of Oxford, Oxford OX1 3UQ, United Kingdom; email: [email protected] 2 Center for Economic and Policy Research, London EC1V 0DX, United Kingdom 3 IZA Institute of Labor Economics, 53113 Bonn, Germany
  • Vol. 12:525-546 (Volume publication date August 2020) https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-economics-082119-121914
  • First published as a Review in Advance on May 01, 2020
  • Copyright © 2020 by Annual Reviews. All rights reserved

This article reviews the economic literature on informality, its causes, and its consequences for development. It covers a comprehensive body of research that ranges from well-identified experimental studies to equilibrium macro models, and which more recently includes structural models that integrate both micro and macro effects. The results available in the literature indicate that lowering the costs of formality is not an effective policy to reduce informality but may generate positive aggregate effects, such as higher output and total factor productivity (TFP). The most effective formalization policy is to increase enforcement on the extensive margin but not on the intensive margin of informality. The former generates substantial gains in aggregate TFP and output, without necessarily increasing unemployment. However, the overall welfare impacts are likely to depend on the transitional dynamics between steady states, which remains an open area for future research.

Article metrics loading...

Full text loading...

Literature Cited

  • Akcigit U , Alp H , Peters M 2018 . Lack of selection and limits to delegation: firm dynamics in developing countries NBER Work. Pap 21905 [Google Scholar]
  • Albrecht J , Navarro L , Vroman S 2009 . The effects of labour market policies in an economy with an informal sector. Econ. J. 119 : 1105– 29 [Google Scholar]
  • Allen J , Nataraj S , Schipper TC 2018 . Strict duality and overlapping productivity distributions between formal and informal firms. J. Dev. Econ. 135 : 534– 54 [Google Scholar]
  • Almeida R , Carneiro P. 2009 . Enforcement of labor regulation and firm size. J. Comp. Econ. 37 : 28– 46 [Google Scholar]
  • Almeida R , Carneiro P. 2012 . Enforcement of labor regulation and informality. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 4 : 64– 89 [Google Scholar]
  • Almeida RK , Poole JP. 2017 . Trade and labor reallocation with heterogeneous enforcement of labor regulations. J. Dev. Econ. 126 : 154– 66 [Google Scholar]
  • Arias J , Azuara O , Bernal P , Heckman JJ , Villarreal C 2010 . Policies to promote growth and economic efficiency in Mexico NBER Work. Pap 16554 [Google Scholar]
  • Auriol E , Warlters M. 2005 . Taxation base in developing countries. J. Public Econ. 89 : 625– 46 [Google Scholar]
  • Azuara O , Marinescu I. 2013 . Informality and the expansion of social protection programs: evidence from Mexico. J. Health Econ. 32 : 938– 50 [Google Scholar]
  • Banerjee AV , Hanna R , Kreindler GE , Olken BA 2017 . Debunking the stereotype of the lazy welfare recipient: evidence from cash transfer programs. World Bank Res. Obs. 32 : 155– 84 [Google Scholar]
  • Bargain O , Kwenda P. 2014 . The informal sector wage gap: new evidence using quantile estimations on panel data. Econ. Dev. Cult. Change 63 : 117– 53 [Google Scholar]
  • Benhassine N , McKenzie D , Pouliquen V , Santini M 2018 . Does inducing informal firms to formalize make sense? Experimental evidence from Benin. J. Public Econ. 157 : 1– 14 [Google Scholar]
  • Bergolo M , Cruces G. 2018 . The anatomy of behavioral responses to social assistance when informal employment is high Unpublished manuscript, Univ. República Montevideo, Urug.: [Google Scholar]
  • Bobba M , Flabbi L , Levy S 2017 . Labor market search, informality and schooling investments IZA Discuss. Pap. 11170, Inst. Labor Econ Bonn, Ger.: [Google Scholar]
  • Bobba M , Flabbi L , Levy S , Tejada M 2019 . Labor market search, informality, and on-the-job human capital accumulation. J. Econom. In press [Google Scholar]
  • Boeri T , Garibaldi P. 2005 . Shadow sorting. NBER Macroeconomics Annual C Pissarides, J Frenkel 125– 63 Cambridge, MA: MIT Press [Google Scholar]
  • Bosch M , Campos-Vazquez RM. 2014 . The trade-offs of welfare policies in labor markets with informal jobs: the case of the “Seguro Popular” program in Mexico. Am. Econ. J. Econ. Policy 6 : 71– 99 [Google Scholar]
  • Bosch M , Esteban-Pretel J. 2012 . Job creation and job destruction in the presence of informal markets. J. Dev. Econ. 98 : 270– 86 [Google Scholar]
  • Bosch M , Esteban-Pretel J. 2015 . The labor market effects of introducing unemployment benefits in an economy with high informality. Eur. Econ. Rev. 75 : 1– 17 [Google Scholar]
  • Bosch M , Goñi-Pacchioni E , Maloney W 2012 . Trade liberalization, labor reforms and formal–informal employment dynamics. Labour Econ 19 : 653– 67 [Google Scholar]
  • Bosch M , Maloney WF. 2010 . Comparative analysis of labor market dynamics using Markov processes: an application to informality. Labour Econ 17 : 621– 31 [Google Scholar]
  • Botelho F , Ponczek V. 2011 . Segmentation in the Brazilian labor market. Econ. Dev. Cult. Change 59 : 437– 63 [Google Scholar]
  • Botero JC , Djankov S , Porta RL , Lopez-de-Silanes F , Shleifer A 2004 . The regulation of labor. Q. J. Econ. 119 : 1339– 82 [Google Scholar]
  • Bracha A , Burke MA. 2016 . Who counts as employed? Informal work, employment status, and labor market slack Work. Pap., Fed. Reserve Bank Boston Boston, MA: [Google Scholar]
  • Bracha A , Burke MA. 2018 . Wage inflation and informal work. Econ. Lett. 171 : 159– 63 [Google Scholar]
  • Bruhn M. 2011 . License to sell: the effect of business registration reform on entrepreneurial activity in Mexico. Rev. Econ. Stat. 93 : 382– 86 [Google Scholar]
  • Bruhn M , McKenzie D. 2014 . Entry regulation and the formalization of microenterprises in developing countries. World Bank Res. Obs. 29 : 186– 201 [Google Scholar]
  • Busso M , Fazio M , Algazi S 2012 . (In)formal and (un)productive: the productivity costs of excessive informality in Mexico. IDB Work. Pap. IDB-WP-341, Inter-Am. Dev. Bank Washington, DC: [Google Scholar]
  • Camacho A , Conover E , Hoyos A 2013 . Effects of Colombia's social protection system on workers' choice between formal and informal employment. World Bank Econ. Rev. 28 : 446– 66 [Google Scholar]
  • Catão LA , Pagés C , Rosales MF 2009 . Financial dependence, formal credit, and informal jobs: new evidence from Brazilian household data IZA Discuss. Pap. 4609, Inst. Labor Econ Bonn, Ger.: [Google Scholar]
  • Charlot O , Malherbet F , Terra C 2015 . Informality in developing economies: regulation and fiscal policies. J. Econ. Dyn. Control 51 : 1– 27 [Google Scholar]
  • Cisneros-Acevedo C. 2019 . Unfolding trade effect in two margins of informality: the Peruvian case Job Mark. Pap., Univ. Nottingham Nottingham, UK: [Google Scholar]
  • Conti G , Ginja R , Narita R 2018 . The value of health insurance: a household job search approach IZA Discuss. Pap. 11706, Inst. Labor Econ Bonn, Ger.: [Google Scholar]
  • Cruces G , Porto G , Viollaz M 2018 . Trade liberalization and informality in Argentina: exploring the adjustment mechanisms. Lat. Am. Econ. Rev. 27 : 13 [Google Scholar]
  • Dabla-Norris E , Gradstein M , Inchauste G 2008 . What causes firms to hide output? The determinants of informality. J. Dev. Econ. 85 : 1– 27 [Google Scholar]
  • de Andrade GH , Bruhn M , McKenzie D 2016 . A helping hand or the long arm of the law? Experimental evidence on what governments can do to formalize firms. World Bank Econ. Rev. 30 : 24– 54 [Google Scholar]
  • De Brauw A , Gilligan DO , Hoddinott J , Roy S 2015 . Bolsa Família and household labor supply. Econ. Dev. Cult. Change 63 : 423– 57 [Google Scholar]
  • De Giorgi G , Rahman A 2013 . SME's registration: evidence from an RCT in Bangladesh. Econ. Lett. 120 : 573– 78 [Google Scholar]
  • de la Parra B. 2016 . Formal firms, informal workers and household labor supply in Mexico Job Mark. Pap., Univ Chicago, Chicago: [Google Scholar]
  • De Mel S , McKenzie D , Woodruff C 2013 . The demand for, and consequences of, formalization among informal firms in Sri Lanka. Am. Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 5 : 122– 50 [Google Scholar]
  • De Paula A , Scheinkman JA 2010 . Value-added taxes, chain effects, and informality. Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 2 : 195– 221 [Google Scholar]
  • De Paula A , Scheinkman JA 2011 . The informal sector: an equilibrium model and some empirical evidence. Rev. Income Wealth 57 : S8– 26 [Google Scholar]
  • De Soto H. 1989 . The Other Path: The Economic Answer to Terrorism New York: Harper & Row [Google Scholar]
  • D'Erasmo PN. 2016 . Access to credit and the size of the formal sector. Economa 16 : 143– 99 [Google Scholar]
  • D'Erasmo PN , Boedo H. 2012 . Financial structure, informality and development. J. Monet. Econ. 59 : 286– 302 [Google Scholar]
  • Dix-Carneiro R , Goldberg PK , Meghir C , Ulyssea G 2019 . Trade and informality in the presence of labor market frictions and regulations Unpublished manuscript, Duke Univ Durham, NC: [Google Scholar]
  • Dix-Carneiro R , Kovak BK. 2019 . Margins of labor market adjustment to trade. J. Int. Econ. 117 : 125– 42 [Google Scholar]
  • Djankov S , Ganser T , McLiesh C , Ramalho R , Shleifer A 2010 . The effect of corporate taxes on investment and entrepreneurship. Am. Econ. J. Macroecon. 2 : 31– 64 [Google Scholar]
  • Djankov S , Porta RL , Lopez-de-Silanes F , Shleifer A 2002 . The regulation of entry. Q. J. Econ. 117 : 1– 37 [Google Scholar]
  • El Badaoui E , Strobl E , Walsh F 2010 . The formal sector wage premium and firm size. J. Dev. Econ. 91 : 37– 47 [Google Scholar]
  • Eslava M , Haltiwanger JC , Pinzón A 2019 . Job creation in Colombia versus the US: “Up or out dynamics” meets the “life cycle of plants.” NBER Work. Pap 25550 [Google Scholar]
  • Fajnzylber P , Maloney WF , Montes-Rojas GV 2011 . Does formality improve micro-firm performance? Evidence from the Brazilian SIMPLES program. J. Dev. Econ. 94 : 262– 76 [Google Scholar]
  • Fields G. 1990 . Labour market modelling and the urban informal sector: theory and evidence. The Informal Sector Revisited D Turnham, B Salome, A Schwarz 49– 69 Paris: OECD [Google Scholar]
  • Fortin B , Marceau N , Savard L 1997 . Taxation, wage controls and the informal sector. J. Public Econ. 66 : 293– 312 [Google Scholar]
  • Friedman E , Johnson S , Kaufmann D , Zoido-Lobaton P 2000 . Dodging the grabbing hand: the determinants of unofficial activity in 69 countries. J. Public Econ. 76 : 459– 93 [Google Scholar]
  • Fugazza M , Jacques JF. 2004 . Labor market institutions, taxation and the underground economy. J. Public Econ. 88 : 395– 418 [Google Scholar]
  • Funkhouser E. 1996 . The urban informal sector in Central America: household survey evidence. World Dev 24 : 1737– 51 [Google Scholar]
  • Galiani S , Weinschelbaum F. 2012 . Modelling informality formally: households and firms. Econ. Inq. 50 : 821– 38 [Google Scholar]
  • Garcia IL. 2015 . Human capital and labor informality in Chile: a life-cycle approach RAND Work. Pap. WR-1087, RAND Corp Santa Monica, CA: https://www.rand.org/pubs/working_papers/WR1087.html [Google Scholar]
  • Garganta S , Gasparini L. 2015 . The impact of a social program on labor informality: the case of AUH in Argentina. J. Dev. Econ. 115 : 99– 110 [Google Scholar]
  • Gasparini L , Tornarolli L. 2009 . Labor informality in Latin America and the Caribbean: patterns and trends from household survey microdata. Desarro. Soc. 2009 : 13– 80 [Google Scholar]
  • Gerard F , Gonzaga G. 2018 . Informal labor and the efficiency cost of social programs: evidence from the Brazilian unemployment insurance program NBER Work. Pap 22608 [Google Scholar]
  • Goldberg PK , Pavcnik N. 2003 . The response of the informal sector to trade liberalization. J. Dev. Econ. 72 : 463– 96 [Google Scholar]
  • Gomes D , Iachan F , Santos C 2018 . Labor earnings dynamics with a large informal sector Unpublished manuscript, Univ. Alberta Edmonton, Can.: [Google Scholar]
  • Gong X , Van Soest A 2002 . Wage differentials and mobility in the urban labour market: a panel data analysis for Mexico. Labour Econ 9 : 513– 29 [Google Scholar]
  • Haanwinckel D , Soares RR. 2016 . Workforce composition, productivity, and labor regulations in a compensating differentials theory of informality IZA Discuss. Pap. 9951, Inst. Labor Econ Bonn, Ger.: [Google Scholar]
  • Hsieh CT , Klenow PJ. 2014 . The life cycle of plants in India and Mexico. Q. J. Econ. 129 : 1035– 84 [Google Scholar]
  • Hsieh CT , Olken B. 2014 . The missing “missing middle.”. J. Econ. Perspect. 28 : 89– 108 [Google Scholar]
  • Johnson S , Kaufmann D , Zoido-Lobaton P 1998 . Regulatory discretion and the unofficial economy. Am. Econ. Rev. 88 : 387– 92 [Google Scholar]
  • Joubert C. 2015 . Pension design with a large informal labor market: evidence from Chile. Int. Econ. Rev. 56 : 673– 94 [Google Scholar]
  • Kaplan DS , Piedra E , Seira E 2011 . Entry regulation and business start-ups: evidence from Mexico. J. Public Econ. 95 : 1501– 15 [Google Scholar]
  • Keane MP , Wolpin KI. 1997 . The career decisions of young men. J. Political Econ. 105 : 473– 522 [Google Scholar]
  • La Porta R , Shleifer A 2008 . The unofficial economy and economic development. Brook. Pap. Econ. Act. 105 : 473– 522 [Google Scholar]
  • La Porta R , Shleifer A 2014 . Informality and development. J. Econ. Perspect. 28 : 109– 26 [Google Scholar]
  • Levy S. 2008 . Good Intentions, Bad Outcomes: Social Policy, Informality, and Economic Growth in Mexico Washington, DC: Brook. Inst. Press [Google Scholar]
  • Loayza NA. 1996 . The economics of the informal sector: a simple model and some empirical evidence from Latin America. Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Ser. Public Policy 45 : 129– 62 [Google Scholar]
  • López JJ. 2017 . A quantitative theory of tax evasion. J. Macroecon. 53 : 107– 26 [Google Scholar]
  • Lopez-Martin B. 2019 . Informal sector misallocation. Macroecon. Dyn. 23 : 3065– 98 [Google Scholar]
  • Magnac T. 1991 . Segmented or competitive labour markets. Econometrica 59 : 165– 87 [Google Scholar]
  • Maloney W. 1999 . Does informality imply segmentation in urban labor markets? Evidence from sectoral transitions in Mexico. World Bank Econ. Rev. 13 : 275– 302 [Google Scholar]
  • Margolis DN , Navarro L , Robalino DA 2012 . Unemployment insurance, job search and informal employment IZA Discuss. Pap. 6660, Inst. Labor Econ Bonn, Ger.: [Google Scholar]
  • McCaig B , Pavcnik N. 2018 . Export markets and labor allocation in a low-income country. Am. Econ. Rev. 108 : 1899– 941 [Google Scholar]
  • Meghir C , Narita R , Robin JM 2015 . Wages and informality in developing countries. Am. Econ. Rev. 105 : 1509– 46 [Google Scholar]
  • Monteiro J , Assunção JJ. 2012 . Coming out of the shadows? Estimating the impact of bureaucracy simplification and tax cut on formality in Brazilian microenterprises. J. Dev. Econ. 99 : 105– 15 [Google Scholar]
  • Naritomi J. 2019 . Consumers as tax auditors. Am. Econ. Rev. 109 : 3031– 72 [Google Scholar]
  • Ordonez JCL. 2014 . Tax collection, the informal sector, and productivity. Rev. Econ. Dyn. 17 : 262– 86 [Google Scholar]
  • Paes de Barros R. 1988 . On the empirical content of the formal-informal labor market segmentation hypothesis Work. Pap., Econ. Res. Cent.–NORC, Univ Chicago, Chicago: [Google Scholar]
  • Pagés C , Stampini M. 2009 . No education, no good jobs? Evidence on the relationship between education and labor market segmentation. J. Comp. Econ. 37 : 387– 401 [Google Scholar]
  • Paz LS. 2014 . The impacts of trade liberalization on informal labor markets: a theoretical and empirical evaluation of the Brazilian case. J. Int. Econ. 92 : 330– 48 [Google Scholar]
  • Perry G , Maloney W , Arias O , Fajnzylber P , Mason A , Saavedra-Chanduvi J 2007 . Informality: Exit or Exclusion Washington, DC: World Bank [Google Scholar]
  • Peters M. 2019 . Heterogeneous mark-ups, growth and endogenous misallocation Unpublished manuscript, Yale Univ New Haven, CT: [Google Scholar]
  • Piza C. 2018 . Out of the shadows? Revisiting the impact of the Brazilian SIMPLES program on firms' formalization rates. J. Dev. Econ. 134 : 125– 32 [Google Scholar]
  • Pomeranz D. 2015 . No taxation without information: deterrence and self-enforcement in the value added tax. Am. Econ. Rev. 105 : 2539– 69 [Google Scholar]
  • Ponczek V , Ulyssea G. 2019 . Is informality an employment buffer? Evidence from the trade liberalization in Brazil Unpublished manuscript, São Paulo Sch. Econ. São Paulo, Braz.: [Google Scholar]
  • Prado M. 2011 . Government policy in the formal and informal sectors. Eur. Econ. Rev. 55 : 1120– 36 [Google Scholar]
  • Pratap S , Quintin E. 2006 . Are labor markets segmented in developing countries? A semiparametric approach. Eur. Econ. Rev. 50 : 1817– 41 [Google Scholar]
  • Quintin E. 2008 . Contract enforcement and the size of the informal economy. Econ. Theory 37 : 395– 416 [Google Scholar]
  • Rajan RG , Zingales L. 1998 . Financial dependence and growth. Am. Econ. Rev. 88 : 559– 86 [Google Scholar]
  • Rauch JE. 1991 . Modelling the informal sector formally. J. Dev. Econ. 35 : 33– 47 [Google Scholar]
  • Rocha R , Ulyssea G , Rachter L 2018 . Do lower taxes reduce informality? Evidence from Brazil. J. Dev. Econ. 134 : 28– 49 [Google Scholar]
  • Schneider F , Enste D. 2000 . Shadow economies: size, causes and consequences. J. Econ. Lit. 38 : 77– 114 [Google Scholar]
  • Straub S. 2005 . Informal sector: the credit market channel. J. Dev. Econ. 78 : 299– 321 [Google Scholar]
  • Ulyssea G. 2010a . The formal-informal labor market segmentation hypothesis revisited. Braz. Rev. Econom. 30 : 311– 34 [Google Scholar]
  • Ulyssea G. 2010b . Regulation of entry, labor market institutions and the informal sector. J. Dev. Econ. 91 : 87– 99 [Google Scholar]
  • Ulyssea G. 2018 . Firms, informality, and development: theory and evidence from Brazil. Am. Econ. Rev. 108 : 2015– 47 [Google Scholar]

Data & Media loading...

  • Article Type: Review Article

Most Read This Month

Most cited most cited rss feed, power laws in economics and finance, the gravity model, the china shock: learning from labor-market adjustment to large changes in trade, microeconomics of technology adoption, financial literacy, financial education, and economic outcomes, gender and competition, corruption in developing countries, the economics of human development and social mobility, the roots of gender inequality in developing countries, weak instruments in instrumental variables regression: theory and practice.

Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.

To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to  upgrade your browser .

Enter the email address you signed up with and we'll email you a reset link.

  • We're Hiring!
  • Help Center

paper cover thumbnail

THE ROLE OF THE INFORMAL SECTOR IN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT IN AFRICA

Profile image of Marwa Zaki

Related Papers

Ahmed El-Bakly

Informality has been a challenge for Egypt for some decade with the informal employment growing at a faster rate than the formal one and it accounts for about 40% of the total labour in 2012. Data series on new entrants to the labour markets (18+) show that in 1969 around 20% were disproportionately drawn into informal sector, increased to 70% in 1998. Recent data in 2014 suggest that this trend remains true. The negative impacts of informality are not restricted to individuals, households or institutions that are working in the informal sector but on the economy as a whole. Many attempts are trying to deal with informality for different purposes, some attempt to integrate informal sector into formal one, others see the economic unites or individuals belong to the informal sector as potential tax payers. Others are seeking to find decent work in the informal sector. Formalising the informal sector, encouraging people to join the formal sector, or recommending mandatory legislative, executive and judicial reforms aiming at depriving individual from joining the informal sector requires conceptualizing the informal sector and identifies the framework in which it operates and examining factors that influence people’s choices in entering labour markets, where the current paper is trying to uncover. The paper provides a discussion on the informal sector conceptualisation through range of literature on the Less Developed Countries with the main focus on Egypt. The discussion covers the terms and definitions used, the framework in which the informal sector theoretically operates, the determinants and factors that assumed or explored to affect the informal sector whether the starting point or its growth. The main result is that a universal definition of the informal sector cannot hold true for every single country context. In addition, instead of defining the informal sector unites a shift occurred toward defining the informal labour market workers. The criteria suggested to identify the informal sector workers include non-registration ofthe workplace, lack of contract, lack of social insurance and lack of health insurance. The conceptualisation and the framework in which the informal sector operates have changed over time. From the tripartite division of activity that failed to represent the heterogeneity of activities found under each subsystem, to the sectorist school that view the informal and the formal parts of the economy as two sectors operating under one economic system characterised by either a complementarity or competitiveness relationship. Informal sector within the Arab countries is assumed to be operating within the sectorist view. A shift of discourse on notion of the informal sector in Egypt is a substantial change, from the notion “margins” of the “modern” economy to the “engine of growth” of the economy. Till the end of the 1960s, the informal sector (margins population) was a problematic segment. After 1960’s, this problematic segment became a solution to the economic crisis just by redefining it to the “engine of growth” and suggesting that it can play an important role in addressing employment crisis. It seems that the determinants or factors that affect the growth of the informal sector differ between Developed and Developing Countries, while there are common factors between the two groups that affect its growth. The failure of the modern economy in the Developed Countries to provide sufficient jobs for the growing number of job seekers could be the starting point of the informal sector, while the sudden penetration of capitalism associated with twentieth-century techniques may have created the initiatives of the informal sector in the Developing Countries. On the other hand, informal sector growth in Developed and Developing Countries is affected by same factors: regulations and legislation, economic recession, and macro-economic policies. On the micro level factor, poverty, education, and skill level, along with the lack of jobs in the formal sector, are those factors that influence the growth of the informal sector.

essay for informal sector

Informality has always been a challenge for Egypt as a developing country. The informal employment has jumped from 30.7 per cent in 1998 to 40 per cent in 2012. The main reasons behind the increasing informality are varied, numerous and different. Moreover, the negative impacts of informality are not only confined to the individuals, households or companies that are working in the informal sector but on the economy of Egypt as a whole. Hence, an integratedregulatory approach must be adopted to rescue Egypt’s economy and get it out of the unforeseen future.

Shirin Motala

Oxford Handbooks Online

P. Mbaye , Nancy Benjamin

Debre Stephen

Clemens P L Wilbertz

Jacques Charmes

Mario Biggeri

Olabisi Yusuff

Development and Change

Kate Meagher

Loading Preview

Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.

RELATED PAPERS

Munyae Mulinge

Stéphane Lagrée

ILO Global Employment Policy Review, Background Paper N°2

Anna Kiaga , Vicky Leung

Friedrich G Schneider

Henrika Langen

Alia El Mahdi

Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung, Economic Policies for Social Justice

Friedrich-Ebert-Stiftung Middle East and North Africa

Imraan Valodia

Gita Subrahmanyam

Hassan Essop

beckline mukete

Africa Journal of Management

Katia De Melo Galdino

… ), and Institute for the Study of Labor (IZA). http://www. …

Sher Verick

Personal Wealth from a Global Perspective

Sangeeta Pratap

Amina Desouky

Robert Kappel

World Bank, Understanding Regulation, Oxford …

Jennifer Bremer

Tanzanian Economic Review

Upenyu Sakarombe

Elias Zewdie

Racha Ramadan

Reza Arabsheibani , Andrew Henley , Francisco Carneiro

Journal of Business and Economic Development

Aïcha TIENDREBEOGO

  •   We're Hiring!
  •   Help Center
  • Find new research papers in:
  • Health Sciences
  • Earth Sciences
  • Cognitive Science
  • Mathematics
  • Computer Science
  • Academia ©2024

CHOGM

Blog: Five ways governments can help small businesses in the informal sector survive COVID-19

essay for informal sector

In Africa, micro, small and medium-size enterprises (MSMEs) in the informal economy are particularly vulnerable to economic impacts of the COVID-19 pandemic.

Blog by Amrita Saha, Institute of Development Studies and Opeyemi Abebe, Adviser and Head of Trade Competitiveness Section at the Commonwealth Secretariat

In Africa, micro, small and medium-size enterprises (MSMEs) in the informal economy are particularly vulnerable to economic impacts of the COVID-19 pandemic. Consumers are demanding and spending less, leading to decreasing revenues, liquidity problems, reduced output and layoffs.

These small businesses are usually engaged in agriculture, retail trade, transportation or construction. An average of 86 per cent of Africans employed are in the informal economy, with women constituting a large part of these numbers. Safeguarding firms and workers in the informal sector will require a mix of swift context-specific short-term and more medium to longer-term measures that focus on building resilience and capabilities.

A new report commissioned by the Commonwealth Secretariat proposes five recommendations on how governments can help ensure their survival:

1. Health and safety guidelines and support schemes for informal workers

Informal sector workers are highly vulnerable to getting infected as they mostly live and work in congested spaces and lack adequate access to water and clean sanitation. Hygiene and sanitation are critical.

As a short-term strategy, African governments can immediately put in place health guidelines for informal traders, as has been done in South Africa. In the medium to long-term, health insurance schemes that afford significant protection for workers in the informal sector, such as Ghana’s National Health Insurance Scheme, can provide better prenatal care, preventive health check-ups and attention from trained health professionals.

2. Adequate short-term welfare support with coverage from public works programs

To reduce the risk of extreme poverty and food insecurity, governments are announcing online payments, in-kind transfers (food distribution) and social grants. However, access to these measures can be complex and more effective and targeted social safety nets for the informal sector are needed.

Cash transfers can be particularly effective as macro-economic stabilizers, since they can take effect with less delay than other discretionary fiscal measures. However, in the medium to long-term, generating employment through paid work opportunities and public works programmes will be important.

3. Maintaining liquidity for firms and re-thinking operating models

To survive the crisis, small businesses in the informal sector need urgent liquidity support. As of May 2020, fiscal policy stimulus vary greatly across countries, ranging from 0.1 to 4 per cent of GDP.

Such short-term increase in the liquidity of MSMEs and should go through the channels that entrepreneurs already know and trust. This means community-based financial and microfinance institutions should be considered essential services during the crisis, and provided emergency liquidity, if within regulation.

The crisis will force a fundamental rethinking of business and operating models that will transform the small business sector for years to come. Short-term measures may provide immediate support, but do little to build long-term sustainability. This requires a structural reduction the finance gap for MSMEs by extending microfinance systems and including other services such insurance, technical assistance in accessing loans and business trainings.

4. Adjusting to supply chain disruptions plus private sector development interventions

Value chain disruptions have huge impacts, as MSMEs in the informal sector rely on day-to-day sales for survival. To avoid insolvencies in the short-term, these businesses will increasingly rely on stimulus measures that lower operational costs and waive existing debts.

Expanding business links is also possible, whereby large, formal businesses can work with small, informal businesses as their outlets or distributors of essential goods to people’s doorsteps. Stimulus packages should improve working spaces and infrastructure of the informal economy, such as communal markets, in a way that promotes social distancing. This would allow them to become operational in the short-term.

In the long-term, business performance and competitiveness could be enhanced through more comprehensive private sector development interventions. These should combine access to finance, consulting and business training with industry-specific networking, regulations, standards, innovation and linkage programmes.

5. Structural policies for resilience

Resilience will depend on structural policies that support training and resources, provide information and invest in building capabilities. In the short-term, these should help MSMEs adopt new working modes and digital technologies that respond to the new reality of COVID-19, such as teleworking, online retail or home delivery.

However, this requires some basic infrastructure in place (such as internet connection) and familiarity with digital platforms, along with consumer demand for such services. Less than 30 per cent of the African population has access to the internet, compared to 90 per cent in advanced countries and 60 per cent in other developing countries. At the same time, mobile money services are on the rise amongst African small businesses, increasing productivity, turnover and revenues, and credibility.

Medium to long-term digital transformation can help ensure MSMEs can bounce back strongly. Simple digital solutions and training that do not require large upfront capital outlay will make it easier to adapt.

In conclusion, policymakers will have to assess the situation and be innovative and adaptive in responding to gaps in their proposed measures. Overall, short-term measures to help the informal MSME sector should be linked with longer-term resilience programmes for more sustainable post-COVID-19 recovery.

Related content

trade

Launch of Commonwealth-UNESCAP Joint Report on Digital and Sustainable Trade Facilitation in the Commonwealth

Birds-eye view of St Kitts and Nevis

Blog: Tax revenue in Commonwealth Small States - A tax-to-GDP analysis

People attend a workshop

Lessons from Maldives on how to design projects and unlock resources

  • Accounting Career
  • Accounting Grade 12
  • Accounting Services
  • Accounting Services in all locations of South Africa
  • Business Knowledge
  • New Companies
  • Tax for Companies
  • Tax for Individuals
  • Uncategorised

There’s no content to show here yet.

Accounting Boss

The Importance of the Informal Sector in the South African Economy

The Importance of the Informal Sector in the South African Economy

The Importance of the Informal Sector in the South African Economy:

essay for informal sector

The informal sector in South Africa is crucial because it contributes 6% to 10% of GDP and employs around 2.5 million people (17% of the workforce) . It plays a significant role in poverty alleviation , entrepreneurship , and provides essential goods and services to communities. Despite challenges like lack of access to finance, targeted government support can enhance its positive impact on the economy.

The informal sector in South Africa is a critical part of the economy, offering substantial contributions and addressing key socio-economic issues.

Table of Contents

Here are specific details and real information highlighting its importance:

Economic Contribution

The informal sector contributes significantly to South Africa’s GDP . While exact figures are challenging to determine due to its unregulated nature, estimates from the South African Reserve Bank and other economic studies suggest that the informal sector contributes approximately 6% to 10% of the national GDP. This contribution is vital for overall economic growth, particularly in a developing country where formal employment is limited.

Employment and Livelihoods

The informal sector is a major employer in South Africa. According to Statistics South Africa , around 2.5 million people are employed in the informal sector, representing about 17% of total employment . This sector provides jobs for a large portion of the labor force that cannot find formal employment, thereby playing a crucial role in reducing unemployment and poverty.

Example : In townships and rural areas, informal traders sell vegetables, clothing, and other goods, providing essential income for their families.

Poverty Alleviation

The informal sector plays a significant role in poverty alleviation . By offering income-generating opportunities, it helps reduce poverty levels. Many individuals working in the informal sector can support their families, pay for education, and improve their living conditions.

essay for informal sector

Example : Street vendors in Johannesburg sell snacks and beverages, earning enough to send their children to school and cover household expenses.

Flexibility and Entrepreneurship

The informal sector encourages entrepreneurship and innovation . Small businesses in this sector often start with minimal capital and can adapt quickly to changing market conditions. This flexibility allows informal businesses to thrive where formal businesses might struggle. The sector serves as a breeding ground for future formal businesses, as many successful entrepreneurs begin informally before transitioning to the formal economy.

Example : A small mechanic shop in a township grows into a formal auto repair business over time.

Consumer Services and Market Access

Informal businesses provide essential goods and services to communities, often at more affordable prices than their formal counterparts. They operate in areas that formal businesses might neglect, ensuring that even marginalized populations have access to basic necessities.

Example : Informal hair salons and barbershops in Soweto offer affordable haircuts and beauty services to local residents.

Real Challenges and Policy Implications

Despite its importance, the informal sector faces several challenges, including lack of access to finance , inadequate infrastructure, and limited legal protection. Addressing these issues requires thoughtful policy interventions. The government can support the informal sector by providing micro-financing options, offering training and capacity-building programs, and improving access to markets and technology.

Example : Initiatives like the Small Enterprise Finance Agency (SEFA) provide micro-loans to informal businesses, helping them expand and formalize.

Statistics and Real Data

  • Economic Impact : The informal sector contributes up to 10% of GDP , according to the South African Reserve Bank.
  • Employment : Employs around 2.5 million people , about 17% of the workforce .
  • Income Generation : Informal traders and small businesses generate significant income, often supporting extended families and local economies.

The informal sector is a vital component of South Africa’s economy, providing significant economic contributions, generating employment, alleviating poverty, and fostering entrepreneurship and market access. Recognizing and supporting this sector through targeted policies can help unlock its full potential, contributing to a more inclusive and resilient economic future for South Africa. Enhancing support for the informal sector is crucial for sustainable development .

Submit Your Details so that Accounting Firms Can Contact You

Leave a reply cancel reply.

Save my name, email, and website in this browser for the next time I comment.

  • Why South Africa Needs to Increase Its Economic Growth Rate
  • Guidelines for Effective Business Reports
  • How Much Does a Franchise Owner Make in South Africa?
  • Why the Circular Flow is Not an Accurate Reflection of Economic Reality
  • Why Are Trade Barriers Necessary for Protecting Employment in South Africa?

World Bank Blogs Logo

Moving from informal to formal sector and what it means for policymakers

Monami dasgupta.

Image

Research Analyst

Join the Conversation

  • Share on mail
  • comments added

COMMENTS

  1. What Is the Informal Economy?

    What is the Informal Economy?

  2. (PDF) Analysing the informal sector in South Africa: Knowledge and

    While the informal sector in South Africa is the 'forgotten' sector in many ways, it provides livelihoods, employment and income for about 2.5 million workers and business owners (2013 data).

  3. Creating jobs, reducing poverty I: Why the informal sector ...

    The book flags the importance of explicitly addressing the informal sector in policy initiatives to boost employment and inclusive growth and reduce poverty. Its last chapter - from which the extracts are drawn - generates a synthesis of key findings on the informal sector and develops the outlines of a constructive policy approach.

  4. The Role of the Informal Sector in the Economic Development of Local

    The informal sector plays a crucial role in the economic development of local areas in South Africa. It encompasses a wide range of economic activities that are not regulated by the government or formalized through official channels. This sector is characterized by its flexibility, low entry barriers, and ability to provide employment opportunities for a

  5. The effect of the informal sector on sustainable development: Evidence

    1 INTRODUCTION. The informal sector has wide-ranging impacts on the economic and social development of developing and less developed countries and it has become a central issue in development discourses (Arvin-Rad et al., 2010; Elbahnasawy et al., 2016; La Porta & Shleifer, 2014).The informal economy that comprises small and medium enterprises and relates to economic activities outside of ...

  6. Informality: Causes and Consequences for Development

    This article reviews the economic literature on informality, its causes, and its consequences for development. It covers a comprehensive body of research that ranges from well-identified experimental studies to equilibrium macro models, and which more recently includes structural models that integrate both micro and macro effects. The results available in the literature indicate that lowering ...

  7. (Pdf) the Role of The Informal Sector in Economic Growth and

    THE ROLE OF THE INFORMAL SECTOR IN ECONOMIC GROWTH AND DEVELOPMENT IN AFRICA By MARWA ZAKI WORKING PAPER Prepared for the LES Africa Summit in London Mar 2017 ABSTRACT The informal sector in the African economies makes a significant contribution toward gross domestic product, which can stimulate economic growth and job creation and which in turn reflected poverty and unemployment.

  8. PDF World Bank Document

    the population. This essay reviews recent literature, methodologies, and relevant Bank studies as a way to share information with country teams interested in expanding their knowledge of the informal sector and related policy debates. Research in a number of regions points to four main areas where development policy can be improved by taking ...

  9. PDF THE INFORMAL SECTOR AND THE CHALLENGES OF DEVELOPMENT IN SOUTH ...

    THE SIZE OF INFORMAL SECTOR. The size of informal sector is estimated to be around R157bn (1US$=R7) 2,5 times the entire size of the agricultural sector. 70% of the mining sector. Trade sector is the largest sub-sector with over 1 million people engaged in this activity. Another 300 000 are engaged in community and social services.

  10. PDF The Informal Economy: Definitions, Theories and Policies

    a brief historical overview of the informal sector concept and related debates, focusing on the four domi-nant schools of thought about the informal economy. It then turns to recent rethinking of the concept, de- ... in the 1954 essay for which he received a Nobel Prize in Economics, that economic development in developing countries would, in ...

  11. Blog: Five ways governments can help small businesses in the informal

    To survive the crisis, small businesses in the informal sector need urgent liquidity support. As of May 2020, fiscal policy stimulus vary greatly across countries, ranging from 0.1 to 4 per cent of GDP. Such short-term increase in the liquidity of MSMEs and should go through the channels that entrepreneurs already know and trust.

  12. Five Things to Know about the Informal Economy

    Five Things to Know about the Informal Economy

  13. PDF Three Essays on the Informal Sector

    Three Essays on the Informal Sector ABSTRACT This thesis consists of three essays that examine: heterogeneity in informal wage employment; access and use of health insurance by individuals in the informal sector; and the gender wage gap in the sector. The first essay uses data from the sixth round of the Ghana Living Standards Sur-

  14. The Importance of the Informal Sector in the South African Economy

    The informal sector in South Africa is crucial because it contributes 6% to 10% of GDP and employs around 2.5 million people (17% of the workforce).It plays a significant role in poverty alleviation, entrepreneurship, and provides essential goods and services to communities.Despite challenges like lack of access to finance, targeted government support can enhance its positive impact on the ...

  15. PDF The Informal Sector in Zambia

    the informal sector. Our goal in this report is to understand the nature of employment in this sector, 6TheInformal Sector is defined by the Labor Force Survey to include workers who are self-employed, work in households and are not covered by social security benefits (check for accura cy)

  16. Essay On Informal Sector

    Essay On Informal Sector. 1068 Words5 Pages. "Developing countries' one third of national income comes from the informal sector. The informal sector reduces the unemployment problems". The third world countries - especially those of Asia and Africa - are under the rapid transition phase and marked by rapid population growth.

  17. Moving from informal to formal sector and what it means for policymakers

    The informal sector connects to the formal sector at multiple points, such as individual transactions, sub-sector networks of commercial relations or a value chain of subcontracted relationships. In a majority of these contacts, the rules of the game are set by the formal sector. Within the informal sector there is always the risk that non-wage ...

  18. PDF A Conceptual Framework for the Informal Economy

    Complete presentation of the informal economy (focusing on the perspective of the economic unit) Not focusing on exhaustiveness. Informal productive activities are: All productive activities carried out by persons and economic units that are - in law or in practice - not covered by formal arrangements. The informal economy is defined as ...

  19. PDF An Analysis of The Informal Economy in Zambia

    The informal economy is an integral part of a larger economic landscape and its importance cannot be overemphasized. From a labour market perspective, informal economy brings together all workers in an informal sector and workers with informal jobs present in formal and informal sectors. It is a diversified set of economic activities, enterprises

  20. PDF Essays on The Economics of The Informal Sector in India

    the informal sector contributed nearly 55 percent to the GDP. This dissertation presents three essays on the economics of the informal sector in India. In Chapter 2, I use Indian labor market data to test whether workers are able to self-select into formal and informal employment. I

  21. Advice for Law School Applicants Interested in Policy, Politics

    While law school is a professional school meant to train lawyers, a J.D. is also a highly versatile graduate degree. Many law graduates practice for only a short time or never practice law at all.