(Stanford users can avoid this Captcha by logging in.)

  • Send to text email RefWorks EndNote printer

National innovation systems : a comparative analysis

Available online.

  • EBSCO Academic Comprehensive Collection

More options

  • Find it at other libraries via WorldCat
  • Contributors

Description

Creators/contributors, contents/summary.

  • Technical innovation and national systems / Richard R. Nelson and Nathan Rosenberg
  • The U.S. national innovation system / David C. Mowery and Nathan Rosenberg
  • The Japanese system of innovation : past, present, and future / Hiroyuki Odagiri and Akira Goto
  • The national system for technical innovation in Germany / Otto Keck
  • National innovation systems : Britain / William Walker
  • The French national system of innovation / François Chesnais
  • The national system of innovation : Italy / Franco Malerba
  • Comparing the Danish and Swedish systems of innovation / Charles Edquist and Bengt-Åke Lundvall
  • The Canadian system of industrial innovation / Donald G. McFetridge
  • The Australian innovation system / Robert G. Gregory
  • National system of industrial innovation : dynamics of capability building in Korea / Linsu Kim
  • National systems supporting technical advance in industry : the case of Taiwan / Chi-Ming Hou and San Gee.
  • National systems supporting technical advance in industry : the Brazilian experience / Carl J. Dahlman and Claudio R. Frischtak
  • National systems of innovation supporting technical advance in industry : the case of Argentina / Jorge M. Katz and Nestor A. Bercovich
  • The innovation system of Israel : description, performance, and outstanding issues / Morris Teubal
  • A retrospective / Richard R. Nelson.

Bibliographic information

Browse related items.

Stanford University

  • Stanford Home
  • Maps & Directions
  • Search Stanford
  • Emergency Info
  • Terms of Use
  • Non-Discrimination
  • Accessibility

© Stanford University , Stanford , California 94305 .

Advertisement

Advertisement

National Innovation Systems in Low-Income and Middle-Income Countries: Re-evaluation of Indicators and Lessons for a Learning Economy in Senegal

  • Published: 24 February 2022
  • Volume 14 , pages 2107–2137, ( 2023 )

Cite this article

national system of innovation case study

  • Vanessa Casadella   ORCID: orcid.org/0000-0002-9483-262X 1 &
  • Sofiane Tahi 1  

2881 Accesses

9 Citations

1 Altmetric

Explore all metrics

The National Innovation System (NIS) approach exists today in multiple terminologies, through a variety of conceptualizations all seeking to provide real means of action to public decision-makers on the issue of innovation, knowledge and economic development. This approach was originally defined by and for high-income countries and not for low- and middle-income countries. Based on the classification of the countries of the World Bank on the Gross National Income of the countries studied, our article proposes to focus on the relevant indicators, not predefined upstream, in order to measure and evaluate the systemic innovation of the low- and middle-income countries, from a learning economy perspective. To answer this, we propose a qualitative model that we validate in the case of Senegal. A low-income economy, it draws most of its efforts not in terms of S&T but more broadly in its learning policy, its reforms on higher education or proposals on entrepreneurship. These efforts are commendable in an economy where macroeconomic conditions are holding back its growth. The originality of our research relates to the implementation of these indicators and the lessons it brings to Senegal on the richness of the exploitation of capacities and skills as a vector of a learning economy.

Similar content being viewed by others

national system of innovation case study

National Innovation Systems in the Asia Pacific: A Comparative Analysis

national system of innovation case study

National systems of innovation

national system of innovation case study

The Changing Role of Science, Technology and Innovation Policy in Building Systems of Innovation: The Case of Mexico

Explore related subjects.

  • Artificial Intelligence

Avoid common mistakes on your manuscript.

After more than 30 years’ analysis on National Innovation Systems (NIS), which mainly originated with Lundvall ( 1992 ), Freeman ( 1987 ) or Nelson ( 1993 ) on the issue of developed countries, it remains important today to pay special attention to its formalisation in low- and middle-income countries. The classification of countries according to their income was established by the World Bank according to the measure of Gross National Income (GNI). If GNI is below 1025 dollars per inhabitant, the country is classified as low, and between 1026 and 4035 dollars, it becomes middle in the lower range. Most sub-Saharan economies are thus judged to be low income, and some Asian countries, such as Cambodia or Mongolia, are classified as middle-income. The interest in this category of country is linked to two reasons: the NIS approach was created for and by developed countries (Japan and Scandinavian countries), suggesting the establishment of predefined criteria by and for developed countries. In addition, innovation and the definition of suitable policies can appear not to be a priority, in view of fundamental problems like poverty or health within these economies (Johnson et al., 2003 ). Accordingly, studies on low- or middle-income NIS were only developed tentatively from the 2000s, when the themes of innovation and learning combined with problems of (under)development. In 2002, out of 750 innovation systems analysed, only 92 were realised in low- or middle-income countries (Xu & Carlsson, 2005 ).

Both a conceptual approach and a tool to formalise scientific and technological policies (Edquist, 1997 ), today, the NIS exists under many different terminologies, through a variety of conceptualisations, all seeking to provide real scope for action to public decision-makers on the issue of innovation and technological development. The question posed here is therefore to know what the relevant indicators are, not predefined in advance, in order to measure and assess systemic innovation in these countries in the light of a learning economy (Lundvall, 1992 ). But this question is ambitious because to consider NIS in this category of country is to consider the great heterogeneity of their trajectories of development: in fact, there are many ways of innovating, learning, resolving problems, and not one single NIS model (Chaminade et al., 2018 ). Consequently, to respond to this, we propose a qualitative model, more suitable to interpret problems of capacities and opportunities for absorbing knowledge of Senegal. The NIS approach should be formalised on criteria suitable for the land that they exploit, especially as theoretical developments proliferate on the new open, sustainable, green and inclusive NIS, and current indicators are not always appropriate or updated.

From an empirical point of view, we chose the case of Senegal for several reasons: it is a poor country, whose fundamental and structural problems are not geared towards innovation. In addition, studies relating to innovation in this country are more oriented towards agricultural innovation (Dugué et al., 2018 ). A case study will thus shed light on the questions of innovation policy, and their realization. Secondary data collected through official documents and government sources will be used in the case study. These data will be qualitatively assessed in our second part.

Our results in Senegal show that these indicators do not appear as a real goal but a means of improving the growth and dissemination of knowledge in these countries. We are therefore interested in the means to be provided to innovate, and not in the technological objectives to be achieved. Thus, Senegal is making a certain number of efforts in this direction, without however seeing the S&T indicators progress strongly. These efforts are local, sectoral and to be interpreted in a broad sense. Our paper is structured as follows: we first establish the current characteristics of NISs in low-income and middle-income countries under the learning economy milestone (§1) before proposing relevant indicators and appropriate in the context of learning economy (§2) and apply them in a low-income economy: the Senegal (§3).

NISs in Low- and Middle-Income Countries: Characteristics and Current Challenges for a Learning Economy

Common and specific characteristics.

If NIS are the subject of a scientific consensus concerning their territorial delimitation, conceptualisation of the latter in low- and middle-income countries is far from being unanimous, despite a certain number of consistent characteristics. Nevertheless, these innovation systems are “open” (Bellon & Niosi, 1994 ) and “globalised” (Binz & Truffer, 2017 ), and the role of multinationals and their activities, through which they can exchange knowledge and technologies through partnerships, remains essential (Watkins et al., 2015 ). There are two opposing approaches in the definition of systemic innovation: a narrow approach linked to R&D activities and to science and technology (Nelson, 1993 ), and a broader approach linked to learning processes (Lundvall, 1992 ). Obviously, it is the “broad” approach (Table 1 ) that merits most attention in low- and middle-income countries. This is because it best corresponds to the definition of their innovation model (Casadella et al., 2015 ).

However, the NIS has characteristics which are similar to all forms of economies examined (Edquist, 1997 ):

It places innovation and learning processes at the centre of the approach

It adopts a holistic and interdisciplinary approach

It uses a historical perspective on the approach and considers innovation processes as evolutionary

It underlines the differences between systems and rejects the notion of optimum

It emphasises the interdependence between systemic components defined as genuine actors

It includes the products and processes of innovation, just like their development and diffusion

It emphasises the central role of institutions as rules of the game

It highlights its diffuse nature

It represents a conceptual structure instead of a real formal theory

We also find characteristics that are more specific and adapted to low- and middle-income countries (Table 2 ).

To take each point, the NIS of these countries is identified more from their conditions of emergence and development. The term construction or emergence (Lundvall et al., 2002 ; Tigabu et al., 2015 ) is mentioned as a substitute for their reproduction, inherent in high-income countries. In low- or middle-income countries, these NIS are constructed or deconstructed because of the disjointed nature of their links and their difficulties in getting out of their technological dependence (Gaillard & Bouabib, 2017 ).

Then, in these countries, innovation, as the capacity to create new products and processes, remains less important than the capacity to use and adapt existing technologies at competitive levels of costs and quality (Lall & Pietrobelli, 2002 ). Innovation is no longer at the frontier of technology but includes strategies of catching up, implemented by those lagging behind.

We also note the heterogeneity of their trajectories of development. These tend to emphasise the many differences between national systems (coming from their history, religion, class, etc.) and to enhance the different stages of development they attain (Edquist, 2001 ). Another characteristic: the NIS approach in developing countries enhances innovation processes in low and medium technologies without being limited to high-tech sectors (Johnson & Lundvall, 2003 ). While innovations in high-tech sectors are sophisticated and based on science and radical innovation, the NIS of these economies is the reflection of conventional perspectives of learning within small traditional structures. Another point relates to the importance of innovation and social entrepreneurship in the NIS approach and relates to the creation of social values through the use of innovative resources (Rao-Nicholson et al., 2017 ). Social innovations follow a mechanism of the reinforcement of institutional arrangements by accumulating public and private interests.

There is another element that is vital for understanding these NIS: the formation of social capital. The construction of innovation results from the institutional framework, which is strongly influenced by society itself. Another element is the position of indigenous knowledge and informal technologies (Jauhiainen & Hooli, 2017 ). Indigenous knowledge, linked to local traditions, was in fact taken into account in innovation policies in the countries of sub-Saharan Africa (Nfila & Jain, 2011 ). Then, the global environment is particularly important, not only to take into account the degree of intensity between national and international (Binz & Truffer, 2017 ), but also to measure the impact of a global crisis on one NIS in particular (Filippetti & Archibugi, 2011 ).

Finally, financing is one of the main problems encountered in infrastructure development and the promotion of industrialisation and agriculture in low- and middle-income countries. Generally, the almost generalised failure of the public banks at the beginning of the 1980s and the establishment of structural adjustment programmes in the 1990s significantly reduced the share of these states in granting of credits. With the gradual disengagement of states, the banks and microfinance institutions play a more important role in innovation transfer (Traore et al., 2020 ). New initiatives and rules developed by these financial institutions helped to diversify the offer of financial services to producers beyond traditional credit mechanisms (Kloeppinger-Todd & Sharma, 2010 ).

Current Issues Around Inclusiveness

Currently, the NIS is no longer only perceived as an instrument relating to technological performances, but as an instrument linked to the understanding of economic development (Lundvall et al., 2002 ). Two themes have recently entered the literature on current innovation systems: that of inclusive innovation and green innovation.

Inclusive innovation shows how the development of technologies, coupled with social policies aimed at reducing inequalities, are important levers in developing economies (Lundvall & Lema, 2014 ). The inclusion can be “passive” or “active”, depending on the degree to which individuals and communities can play an “active” role in economic development. Passive inclusion represents the reduction in income inequalities, creating employment and incentives to increase the income of the poor. Active inclusion considers that segments excluded from society should participate directly, through their rights and contributions, to the process of development and innovation (Heeks et al., 2014 ). The intended goal is wellbeing, improving the quality of life and reducing poverty. These innovations can, in fact, also be considered as a form of social innovation, defined as a product, a process or a technology, or even as an idea, a legislative reference, a social movement, a public intervention or the combination of some of these (Phils et al., 2008 ). Inclusive innovation has an essential place in NIS works to understand how technological and non-technological innovations, realised by the poorest or by all the other actors in society, have been used by all organisations, communities and civil societies.

Still in a perspective of new approaches, sustainable development is an important theme, which has not been heard about enough in NIS works (Johnson et al., 2017 ). A plethora of concepts has emerged from sustainable innovations: environmental innovations, low carbon innovations, eco-innovation and socio-ecological innovations (Franceschini et al., 2016 ). All these definitions have in common the fact of finding technological, social or institutional solutions to improve the environmental impact on human activity (Chaminade et al., 2018 ). Superimposed on the NIS approach, a system of sustainable innovation is made up of social, human and natural elements, as well as relations which interact in the production, diffusion and use of new and economically profitable knowledge (Segura-Bonilla, 2003 ). Consequently, we can envisage an NIS for sustainable development or sustainable innovation as a new twenty-first century opportunity (Segura-Bonilla, 2003 ).

The Place of the Learning Economy in NIS Literature

Learning theories emanate from the Scandinavian School (Lundvall, 1992 ).

They lie at the crossroads of evolutionary and institutionalist theories and represent the central core of the NIS. Two principles highlight the role of learning and knowledge within the approach:

The first principle lies in its positioning: the centrality of learning in the NIS theories implies, on the one hand, that the NIS efficiency is a main factor of growth and economic development. This finding tends to mark the opposition with classical economic theories in which the endowments of capital and labour are the keys to economic development. This approach also rejects the position that people who learn do not innovate. On the other hand, it implies that the capacity of a nation to continuously generate new ideas and competencies and thus to accumulate new knowledge is the driving idea of ​the long-term economic prospects of nations.

At the heart of NIS, the learning processes are in permanent connection with the routine activities of production and distribution. The speed and form of learning are essential factors in the competitiveness and creativity of nations. They have multiple aspects, the main ones being learning by doing (Arrow), learning by using (Rosenberg), learning by interacting (Lundvall) but also learning through research, exploration or re-learning processes (Johnson, 1992 ).

The second principle lies in the enhancement of the interactive and institutional framework within the learning process. This perspective introduces the idea of the interactivity mechanism rejecting the hypothesis of unidirectional sequentiality of learning processes. Learning mechanisms are the result of connectivity between those who benefit from new ideas and seek to expand their applicability and those who use them and demonstrate continuously revised needs. On the other hand, learning, as a cumulative process, is incorporated into the institutional dynamics of the NIS. Learning does not take place only by individuals within firms but also within public and private organizations and institutions. If institutions regulate and shape learning channels, they themselves must go through a learning process called institutional learning (Johnson, 1992 ). According to him, it is about the effective capacity of national economies to face their problems through their capacity to learn, to learn to adapt and possibly to change their institutional structures.

However, this theoretical framework will remain restrictive in its initial conception. In fact, in the first work of Lundvall ( 1992 ), the authors limit themselves loosely to “classic” learning processes (learning by doing, using, interacting) while remaining imprecise as to who learns what, in what way and how learning remains linked to innovation processes. Gradually, education, training or individual learning (Edquist, 2001 ) will enter as key components of recent NIS literature (Lundvall & Christensen, 1999 ). The same will be true for the recognition of individual learning within organizations.

The role of learning in the NIS approach takes on a new aspect in that it makes much less reference to restrictive learning processes than to all the learning capacities of firms, organizations and regions (Lundvall et al., 2002 ). In other words, it is more generally an interest in what Johnson et al. calls “the learning capacities as a whole” (Johnson et al., 2003 ), namely the set of learning processes, collective and individual, direct and indirect and the diversity of forms of learning. There are therefore a multitude of paths through which individuals, firms and nations are likely to learn. The learning economy is pervasive, diverse and permeates all parts of the economy. Learning takes place at all levels: technological, organizational, individual and societal. All of these combinations are essential for national capacity building because they determine whether companies, industry groups and states succeed or fail in their growth strategies.

The contextual framework of the learning economy allows NISs to glimpse their full learning perspectives and therefore understand, in the face of the accelerating speed of change, how some NISs respond better than others to the process of change.

Relevant Indicators for NIS in Low- and Middle-Income Countries

The assessment on NIS for low-and middle-income countries encourages us in this regard to select two important elements:

Their specificity despite their very great heterogeneity,

Their objective of dissemination and use of knowledge

Consequently, we will adapt these elements around the construction of relevant indicators.

The Failure of Quantitative Instruments

On the issue of low- and middle-income countries, two forms of studies are envisaged: descriptive studies and formalised studies (Balzat, 2002 ). But the latter are not always relevant in current inclusive logics.

Two forms of studies are most often represented. These are descriptive and formalised studies. They help to achieve purely political strategies and/or aim to enhance the conceptual structure of the approach (Balzat, 2002 ). When they assume a political interest, they are generally carried out by the European Commission, the OECD, UNCTAD or the World Bank; their objective is to develop indicators and a methodology to compare national scientific policies. When they do not have a political purpose, they serve to understand the phenomena of systemic innovation at national level. Amongst descriptive models (Chang & Chen, 2004 ), Liu and White ( 2001 ) identify five activities relating to the innovation process: research, production, users (end use), interactions and education. Their analysis is based on the distribution of activities in innovation processes, mechanisms of control and coordination and information flows. They apply this method to analyse the Chinese NIS through an inter-temporal comparison of the different stages of development. Institutional and organisational differences are thus obtained between the NIS of Communist China and that of democratic China.

Parallel to the descriptive models, formalised models emerged to quantify more “formally” the innovative performance of nations. Some authors seek to construct instruments to track NIS (Godinho et al., 2003 ). For example, Furman et al. ( 2002 ) have proposed the concept of “national innovative capacity” as the capacity of a country to produce and market a technology flow in relation to the national infrastructure, the environment of industrial groups and the nature of links between the two. Each element, infrastructure, environment of clusters and links is measured by variables forming a specific model of decline. In a similar vein, Arcelus and Nasierowsky ( 1999 ) have identified national technological capacities on the basis of a system of structural equations based on inputs, outputs and moderators. Their analysis led to a classification of two groups of countries, technological leaders and other emerging countries, the technological progress of which is based on importing innovations developed abroad. After carrying out initial empirical tests, more recently, they have devised a model with two inputs, two moderators and three outputs. The efficiency of the NIS is based on R&D, as well as on its productivity. The overall idea is to perceive the NIS as an isolated sector of the entire economy.

The most commonly cited index used to measure innovation is the Composite Innovation Index, created by WIPO (Wipo, 2019 ). The 80 indicators proposed range from instruments of conventional measurement, such as investment in R&D, international patent requests and requests for the international registration of brands, to new indicators, such as, in particular, the creation of mobile applications and the export of high technology products. The Potential Innovation Index (PII) is another index used to diagnose the capacity to innovate according to 18 internal activities (Enjolras et al.,  2018 ). However, this index does not take account of the environment of the firm.

More specifically, the indicators defined in the NIS approach are very heterogenous. Currently, three types of these can be distinguished (Lizuka & Hollanders, 2017 ):

Science and Technology indicators (publications, patents, R&D resources, R&D personnel)

Indicators from surveys on innovation, collected from firms, and linked to the results of innovation (% of sales linked to new products, introduction of new products and processes), expenditure on innovation (patents, licences, ideas on personnel training, market analysis) and information on what precedes innovation (sources of knowledge, obstacles to innovate)

Composite indicators, as we have cited above

Many low- and middle-income countries have used these innovation indicators. Except that these are not always suitable, particularly on adaptation to their needs (Tijssen & Hollanders, 2006 ). In addition, these indicators were created by simplifying complex phenomena, and by only emphasising some magnified aspects that are not very representative (Esperand & Sauder, 2012 ). Furthermore, these indicators were created on the basis of research activity, as conceptualised in high-income countries. And yet, as seen recently, the NIS of low- and middle-income countries is constructed more on a logic of learning (formal and informal) than on R&D, strictly speaking. Finally, the indicators influencing S&T have had a very limited effect, particularly because these policies were not aligned with social policies and therefore lacked coordination and a horizontal approach (Lemarchand, 2010 ).

The Relevance of Qualitative Instruments and the Proposed Model

The NIS of low- and middle-income countries is indisputably based on qualitative elements (interpersonal, normative, informal, constructed ex-ante ). But we cannot dismiss the difficulties in quantifying these qualitative aspects. We must, then, absolutely combine macro and micro indicators, as only one micro type bottom-up approach is currently discussed in the literature (Aguirre-Bastos & Weber, 2017 ). It should be supplemented by a top-down approach, of the macro kind, leading us to consider innovation policies to strengthen the capacities of local communities and disadvantaged areas.

Here, the methodology that we have chosen can be found in constructing development blocs (Dahmen, 1989 ). These blocs are identified as qualitative aspects of innovation. They are based on diversified channels of learning and refer to interdependent and interconnected factors associated with technological development. These blocs analyse sequences of complementarities which create the dynamic of the system and produce a potential for development. They thus represent a relevant conceptual structure to analyse the transformations that occur within the NIS.

The proposed model is presented in six development blocs (or subsystems). If we had to classify these subsystems, in line with the work of Arcelus and Nasierowsky ( 1999 ), we would obtain two inputs , two moderators and two outputs . The inputs represent learning capacities; moderators , the elements of the national structure with an impact on inputs/outputs and, finally, the outputs integrated into the “results” from learning efforts.

Among the inputs :

Learning capacities

Learning culture.

Among the moderators :

Learning demands

Learning links.

And finally, among the outputs:

Local readaptation of knowledge;

Improvement in the quality of life.

Learning Capacities

The learning effort represents categories of firms which have spent a sum of money, even minimal, on research activities or activities which aim to produce innovations (Naclerio, 2004 ). Some firms can thus innovate without making any particular efforts (the case of reactive firms which respond to a particular economic situation and stable technologies), innovate by making real efforts (the case of proactive firms or radical innovations) or do not innovate at all. The implicit effort corresponds to the development of new technological knowledge, to a change in communication codes, or interactions between producers and users. Consequently, innovative firms making technological efforts are combined with active learning systems and those which do not make efforts with passive learning systems (Viotti, 2002 ).

Learning capacity presents the potential improvement in access to knowledge. This improves the different possibilities for access to knowledge by strengthening individual and collective skills. Thus, the provision of knowledge in relation to activities to resolve problems is a first necessary condition for our model.

Learning efforts correspond to the five following indicators:

Access to learning institutions

Number of researchers and scientific diaspora

Level of general qualification

Scientific research groups

Situation of firms and learner organisations

Access to institutions is measured by the number of technological institutions, as well as by all the non-technological interfaces (training institutions, chambers of commerce and industry etc.). Access to knowledge institutions helps to measure the level of the democratisation of knowledge.

The existence of a scientific diaspora means that foreign researchers are considered to be an important part of the national research community. The diaspora is a real force for learning, the dynamism of which varies depending on the degree of engagement of public policies. But measuring the number of researchers is not straightforward in view of the many scientific migrations.

Another indicator can be found in the level of qualification of the population. This identifies the level attained by the population through the education rate and literacy of young schoolchildren.

Scientific research groups learn through units (formal) of research and numbers of research projects. This is where we find evidence of the importance of the university activities described earlier (Albuquerque et al., 2015 ).

Finally, the number of SMEs founded on knowledge is a major asset as a driver of economic growth. In low- and middle-income countries, these firms play a role of technological tailors capable of finding tailored solutions by using scientific instruments. Without the presence of these firms, capable of establishing relations with the users of knowledge, speaking the same language and developing the same codes, firms will find it difficult to develop new technologies. These include, in particular, firms which maintain solid links with knowledge networks.

Culture of Learning

The culture of learning (Johnson & Lundvall, 2003 ), representing the diversity of sources of learning, is a qualitative variable that is particularly difficult to quantify because of these tacit and informal aspects. The issue raised here is to define the frequency of firms’ learning activities and assess their composite nature.

Is learning (of a product or a process) a daily activity of firms? How are learning activities organised by actors in an organisation? What are the different learning activities deployed by firms?

Low-income economies are often based on informal learning, and knowledge is generally a form of secret transmitted to the apprentice from descendant to descendant (Oyelaran-Oyeyinka, 2004 ). By transforming codified foreign knowledge into local use, only a small proportion is transferred through formal methods. What remains requires a long heuristic process of imitation, reverse engineering and learning techniques. This non-formal knowledge has direct repercussions for firm performance (Ducatel, 1988 ). As literature on NIS often favour formal institutions, we must look at non-formal knowledge, essential for the process of absorption of technologies.

The following indicators will be established on a microeconomic scale:

Profile of firm learning activities

Frequency of firm learning activities

The first indicator proposes to target firm learning channels in order to understand their main forms. The purpose is, if necessary, to draw out new learning techniques and, through this, to broaden the NIS approach.

As for the frequency of learning activities, this will help us to understand if firms consider learning to be an essential right or if the problems of internal or external conflicts restrict their potential applications.

Demand for Learning

The deployment of learning capacities and the acquisition of technological capacities are linked to opportunities to apply knowledge in the face of problems encountered (Arocena & Sutz, 1999 ). In other words, improving learning cannot be explained as a simple phenomenon based on the supply and demand of knowledge but on supply and demand in relation to the existing institutional framework. What clearly appears in the initial approaches of Von Hippel ( 1988 ) seems to be less so in works on NIS, which tend to underestimate the diversity of knowledge users.

This variable responds to the questions: Who uses? How to use knowledge? Where to use knowledge? With this in mind, the indicators proposed will be the following:

Demand for knowledge from the public sphere

Demand for knowledge from the private sphere

Public demand for knowledge is crucial when we acknowledge that privatisation processes come from political choices.

In order to establish a consistent measure for this moderator, we will consider satisfaction of the state’s internal demand (political strategies, recruitment of researchers, number of projects established, public financing of innovations, regulatory system) and the existence of public demand concerning local needs. From that, we can know where and how the state uses existing knowledge. This public demand is significant. To cite just one example on public financing, public credit favoured agricultural intensification in cash crop areas in sub-Saharan Africa (Témé, 2016 ). It also helped to reindustrialise some sectors by setting up innovative project or relevant fiscal measures. But the limits of public demand have been revealed to be major with the gradual disengagement of states in a certain number of low- and middle-income countries. Private demand therefore appears to be legitimate and recognises the importance of users of knowledge and the influence that they exert on local institutions.

This demand more particularly concerns workers and consumers through private organisations and institutions. Banks and microfinance institutions (MFIs) therefore played a key role in the transfer of innovations, particularly in the agricultural sector. These new actors define their financing policy and establish risk financing strategies with actors specialising in financing innovation. These financial intermediaries are a major category of actors present in national innovation systems (Cooke, 2001 ).

Learning Links

The effectiveness of learning processes depends on the nature of interaction, the proximity of which is not territorial but behavioural. The interactive dimension of learning, learning-by-interacting (inter-firms and intra-firms), is the foundation of diffusion processes and the use of knowledge. According to Oyelaran-Oyeyinka ( 2004 ), a systemic positive dynamic is reproduced at a national level when the following are established: (i) a variety of links requiring offerors, producers and service providers; (ii) a propensity to cooperation and collaboration; (iii) a large number of actors diffusing information and the knowledge needed to produce goods and services; (iv) a propensity to encourage private initiatives by public demand and (v) strong local–global formal and/or informal networking.

In this case, the systemic aspect will include the following points:

Horizontal collaborations

Subcontracting

Links developed with the agricultural, industrial and service sector

Cooperation with suppliers

Collaborations with universities (and other learning interfaces)

Links developed with foreign firms

Local Readaptation of Knowledge

Readaptation is understood to be the result of the efforts (capacities) and demand of learning. This is about finding the trajectories of use of local knowledge. But how can we quantify the degree of readaptation of knowledge or the externalisation of knowledge?

In most studies, the final result, the output, is integrated into the end product or the new process. The defined variable is often an improvement in the product, the process, the organisation of production, new equipment, new products and new processes. Having said this, in low- and middle-income countries, the sought-after aim is not stricto sensu innovation but a number of objectives to be achieved (improvement in learning) regarding exogenous knowledge (scientific and general) and traditional knowledge (inherited from a culture of reference). Indigenous systems of knowledge can, for example, represent these objectives and appear as real engagements between a present and a future situation (Bertelsen & Muller, 2003 ). For example, setting up projects also remains an output relating to building competences. One project shows how knowledge can be diffused and used with a view to an active reappropriation of knowledge (Davies & Hobday, 2005 ).

The proposed sub-indicator is, then, the following:

Objectives achieved by the firm, helping to improve knowledge

Objectives achieved by public decision-makers to improve knowledge

If, for example, the firm has recruited qualified personnel, commits to training plans and the personnel emerge from this with some certification, then we can talk about a real result. Similarly, if public decision-makers encourage real social policies in favour of learning, we can also talk of a result.

Inclusive Innovation and Capabilities

As underlined, works on NIS are currently proposing the variable development as a tool of the NIS approach. The aspects studied take very different forms as long as this is in fine to measure the quality of life of individuals through innovation and learning. But if the theoretical justification is indeed real, empirical studies still remain insufficient. Because we cannot reduce human beings to means of production and these are also a real purpose (Sen, 2000 ), the indicators in question should measure the level of social or political development of individuals.

More specifically, this concerns presenting the preceding output with the following sub-indicators:

Inclusive innovation and social development

Inclusive innovation and political development

These sub-indicators allow us to pose the following questions: has carrying out company projects or the development of indigenous knowledge systems had repercussions for the fertility rate? Infant mortality? Evaluation of the role of women? Or even the quality of public debate? The responses provided vary according to the previous output (variable 5). They can certainly be limited to a short-term social development (example of the role of women in a company project) or to any political development (example of the creation of a home-owners association faced with a contentious project), with the main idea being to integrate the impact of social opportunities in this model.

By way of a recap, the table below provides the summary of the proposed model. Undeniably, var. 1 will come from secondary data, but var. 2 to 6 from field surveys, both through semi-structured interviews, and observations from visits. Data from secondary sources (var. 1) should be input to be able to triangulate the information with its context. As the literature on NIS tends to be static and present very simplified general descriptive studies (Xu & Carlsson, 2005 ), evidently, it is the evolution of the whole system that will interest us and not some comparative approach (Table 3 ).

The Study Case in Senegal

This case study focuses on secondary data collected at the start of 2021. This study focuses on the qualitative variables proposed to define a national innovation system. Some variables have less value than others insofar as they must be accompanied by microeconomic studies (especially for the culture of learning). Before returning to each variable, it is necessary to look at the overall macroeconomic context of the country.

Macroeconomic Conditions

With a population of 15.85 million in 2018, with an average GDP per capita of $1521.95 (World Bank, 2018 ), Senegal is classified by the United Nations (UN) as a least developed country (LDC). It nevertheless displays its political ambition to the status of emerging countries by playing a leading role in regional economies within the West African Economic and Monetary Union (WAEMU). An illustrative example of democracy (although the current situation of violence calls into question the principle of democracy), benefiting from the most important development aid as well as monetary agreements with France within the franc zone (allowing it to avoid any problem of currency availability and any internal monetary slippage), Senegal has inevitably made a number of mistakes in its economic policy, rating it as a least developed country against several UN criteria.

The Senegalese economy has undergone four major phases of development since independence: (i) the period 1960–1983 marked by irregular growth; (ii) the period 1983–1994 corresponding to the exclusive use of internal adjustment, characterized by a lack of investment and a loss of growth and competitiveness; (iii) the post-devaluation decade (1995–2005) marked by further reforms and accelerated growth; and (iv) the post-2005 period characterized by a decline in economic growth. From 2006 onwards, a clear inflection of growth was noted, in connection with factors of fragility and volatility. Indeed, the global economy has experienced a series of shocks of a diverse nature: the food crisis and soaring commodity prices in 2007, soaring oil prices in 2008, the economic and financial crisis resulting from the “subprime mortgage” in 2007/2008, the 2011 earthquake in Japan, the socio-political unrest in the Maghreb and the Middle East in 2011, the sovereign debt crisis in Europe and the USA. In the sub region, the political and security crises also affected the Senegalese economy. Since early 2020, the coronavirus pandemic (COVID-19) has significantly changed the country’s economic outlook. In 2020, growth slowed sharply, falling to an estimated level of 1.3%, with services (such as tourism and transport) and exports being particularly affected.

On the commercial side, Senegal trade balance 2019 is $ − 3.52 billions, a 4.52% increase from 2018. Developments in exports are mainly due to increased sales of peanuts and cotton, while imports are driven by a substantial increase in capital goods and intermediates.

The unemployment rate represents 48% of the total population. According to the international labour organization, it ranks the country among the 3 most affected countries in the world. Footnote 1 Young people play an important role in the overall workforce of the unemployed. But since the individual who does not have his own resources can survive to create his own job on the industrial sector, unemployment would be reserved for privileged groups, and the real tensions would tend to be at the level of underemployment. The informal sector thus emerges as the only alternative for large segments of the population. However, it is characterized by low wages, poor working conditions and a lack of social protection.

We will present learning capacities through the institutional context, learning policies, R&D policies and regional, sectoral S&T policies.

Institutional Landscape

The institutional landscape is relatively dense. At the institutional level, the lead ministry in charge of research Ministry of Higher Education and Research. In the field of agricultural research, the Senegalese Institute of Agricultural Research (ISRA) is under the Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Equipment. The Institute of Food Technology (ITA) is under the supervision of the Ministry of Mines, Industry and Processing of agricultural products and small- and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs). In Senegal, the governance of innovation policy is defined by the Ministry of Higher Education of Technological Research. It is coordinated by a National Agency for Applied Scientific Research. However, the administrative and technical supervision of different ministries and the lack of a single steering of research and innovation result in a dispersion and fragmentation of research through a multiplication and superposition of priorities, a weakness and fragmentation of the sources of Financing and a lack of mechanisms to structure consultation between researchers. Finally, there is a National Academy of Sciences and Techniques which represents a place of recognition of academic knowledge generated by national researchers. Human resources dedicated to research for innovation are structured by the following main institutions (Table 4 ).

However, on the quality aspect of governance, it remains important to talk about clientelism. The Senegalese economy is a rentier economy. Behaviour to increase labour productivity is rare. In order to create a learning society, the political elite must be able to provide leadership on the management of public goods. This leadership requires a realistic and achievable vision of the country’s development. The new social contract defined since 2000 should have encouraged this vision. On the contrary, this new regime has led to the development of political formations dominated, in the main, by the rentier elites (Diallo, 2004 ). Universal clientelism is still very much alive. Untrained government teams cannot grasp the innovative dynamics and identify the difficulties and information needed to make decisions. The action of the state is thereby distorted and devoid of any virtue and of a quest for rationality. It is not surprising that economic, social and cultural issues occupy few places in the political programs of leaders (Dieng, 2000 ). The consequences of this situation reflect an anti-political culture that leads to substitutes for anti-state parties and NGOs. In this perspective, the country’s corruption index (2020) is 29 out of a total of 45 countries. Much progress is yet to be made on this point.

Learning Policies

Since 2013, Senegal has been conducting a Quality, Equity and Transparency Improvement Program in order to plan the main school and poverty reduction reforms until 2025. The program aims to achieve universal primary schooling, equitable access by gender, poverty reduction and skills training for youth and adults. This program, set up after the Ten-Year Education and Training Program (PDEF), aims to catch up on training and education delays in comparison with other developing economies. The country’s total literacy rate in 2017 was 69.5% of which 75.6% for men and 63.5% for women (UNESCO, 2015 ). These figures are constantly being revised upwards. Thus, the main difficulties encountered in education and learning are as follows (PAQUET Report, Ministry of National Education of Senegal, 2013 ):

High cost of schooling (beyond tuition and transport), which explains a massive exit from the school system beyond the college and which affects women in particular

Inadequate reception facilities and deprivation in which a large number of public establishments are located

Difficulty of the state to pay regularly the salaries of the growing number of teachers and supervisory staff

Initial training of teachers sometimes recruited after the baccalaureate

Therefore, to remedy this, the general orientations of PAQUET-EF 2018–2030 pursue the objectives of quality, equity and good governance initially set but reinforce their emphasis on equity of access by reducing vulnerabilities, the development of preschool and the consolidation of the fundamental cycle by integrating all forms of education (including non-formal) and by developing bridges, in particular through the development of vocational guidance systems to promote orientation towards professional fields and techniques.

Senegalese higher education welcomed 160,000 students to its network of universities and higher education institutions in 2017–2018 (French Embassy in Senegal, 2017 ). The significant demographic growth of Senegal and the increase in gross enrolment rates and the number of girls in secondary education have greatly increased the demand for access to higher education. Despite a low success rate for the baccalaureate (35.9% in 2018), the annual flow of baccalaureate holders is constantly increasing, rising from around 9000 in 2000 to more than 53,273 candidates admitted for the 2018 session. Eighty per cent of holders of the baccalaureate enrol in Senegalese higher education thus implying serious problems of overstaffing (French Embassy in Senegal, 2017 ). Projections made by the Ministry of Education, Research and Innovation (MESRI) estimate the student population at 270,000 students in 2022, the goal being to reach 700,000 students by 2027.

Several universities have thus emerged:

University of Sine Saloum El Hadj Ibrahima Niass (USSEIN): It opened in February 2019 with a cohort of 1725 students. It provides training in agriculture and related professions, for food security, sustainable development and prosperity.

Amadou Mokhtar Mbow University (UAM): Located in the new town of Diamniadio, near Dakar; its construction site began in January 2016. UAM is designed to eventually accommodate 30,000 students. It is a university mainly oriented towards science and technology.

Virtual University of Senegal: Created in 2013, the Virtual University of Senegal offers a range of open distance learning courses in the fields of Mathematics/IT, Economic science, Legal Sciences, English and Sociology. In 2018, UVS welcomed 27,000 students, with a projection of 30,000 students in 2019, thus becoming the 2nd university in Senegal. Training is delivered through online courses and support from tutors.

If new universities emerge, the introduction of a lifelong learning policy (vocational training, company training, training leave, etc.) is made difficult in contexts of high industrial concentration and the dominant informal structure of entrepreneurship within a fabric of small and micro enterprises. In Senegal, this policy is trying to develop with the creation of institutions such as ISADE (Institut Supérieur Africain pour le Développement de l’Entreprise). Another constraint is posed by the difficulty of the firms to have centers of formation connected to the system of academic education. The main sources of learning are on-the-job and informal (Casadella, 2010 ). They are poorly adapted (content, speed …) to the absorption of knowledge of technologies that offer the globalization of knowledge related to the digital revolution. The rapid and efficient use of new technologies by a skilled workforce thus requires investment in the training of technological engineering.

As such and since 2014, a new fund, the 3FPT, supports the initial and continuing training of workers in companies and professional organizations, young people seeking qualifications, training centers and institutions but also the quality assurance of vocational and technical training system. This fund is particularly significant, even if it trained just over 18,000 Senegalese in 2018. In this dimension, and following a remarkable weakness in the number of learners in technological professional fields and an imbalance in training levels. Macky Sall asked in 2013 to reorient the higher education system towards science, technology, short vocational training. It has established Higher Institutes of Vocational Education (called “ISEP”) in all regions of the country. The educational project of all ISEPs is based on the skills-based approach and leads to the Higher Diploma of Vocational Education at Bac + 2 level, with a study-workplace alternation. This fund and these institutes are particularly important for the development of learning and competencies. They make it possible to create more demand for knowledge, in a context of professionalization and rapid acquisition of knowledge.

If Senegal has initiated deep reforms in favour of higher education and its professionalization, it is not only to turn to a more suitable labour market but also to avoid a massive brain drain. Each year, the migration of Senegalese students is increasingly strong and concerns more a qualified population. According to UNESCO data, there are 13,876 mobile students abroad (including almost 9000 in France), i.e. a rate of mobility abroad of 7.5%. In sub-Saharan Africa, more broadly, the brain drain is very pronounced and could reach 34 million immigrants in 2050 (IMF Report, 2016 ). The government has therefore acted positively by proposing the construction of new higher establishments, including ISEPs geared towards vocational education. Senegal has also initiated a specific program for the assistance and supervision of its qualified immigrants and created the post of Special Advisor on Immigration to the President of the Republic. Inter-university cooperation has finally been strengthened.

Research & Development (R&D) Policies

The Structural Adjustment Policies of the 1980s destabilized government strategies for investment in scientific and technological capacities and public infrastructure that secured access to water, energy and transport investments. Since the 2000s, they have been renewed in favour of innovation. Implementation in Senegal of the Poverty Reduction Strategy (PRS) of integrated programs, such as the “National Strategy for Economic and Social Development” since 2013, but also the strategic objectives of increasing the budget for R&D and the strengthening of South-South and North–South scientific cooperation are salutary changes for the years to come. A National Consultation on the Future of Higher Education, Research and Innovation was completed in 2013 with a “Priority Reform Program 2013–2017 for Higher Education and Research in Senegal” and a “Plan for the Development of Higher Education and Research”. Since then, and in the latest report “Emerging Senegal Plan 2019–2023”, the government is betting on a clear increase in R&D spending: “The performance recorded will be measured against the percentage of spending allocated to research and development on the GDP, a percentage which should drop from 0.8% in 2015 to 3.98% in 2023” (Emerging Senegal Plan, 2018 ). According to the 2015 UNESCO Science Report, the domestic research and development expenditure of Africa in 2013 accounted for 0.45% of GDP. This corresponded to 1.3% of global research and development spending while Asia’s share was 42% in the same year. Although the state is generally the main source of GERD, foreign funding represents a significant share in Ghana (31%), Senegal (41%) and Burkina Faso (60%) (Unesco, 2015 ). In Senegal, research funding remains mainly oriented towards R&D in the agricultural and food sector (about CFAF 1 billion for agricultural R & D, compared with about 600 million for industrial R&D) and foreign funds.

Sectoral, Regional S&T Policies

Other structures act directly indirectly on S&T but provide support for entrepreneurship:

The agency for the development and supervision of small and medium-sized enterprises (called ADEPME) supports the manager throughout the life of their business: the creation or resumption of an activity, business growth or restructuring.

The mission of the General Delegation for Rapid Entrepreneurship for Women and Youth is to help boost entrepreneurship among women and young people. Informal entrepreneurship occupies a preponderant place in the Senegalese economy and its formalization promotes the inclusion of women and young people, targets generally marginalized by the traditional financial system. Along with these structures, new “learning” projects emerge such as the Sonatel Academy, the first free coding school in Senegal, which aims to become a point of innovation throughout the value chain, with a school, the Fab Lab, a start-up space, which supports the school’s laureates through a personalized acceleration program.

Technological innovation is also promoted by a system of more favourable regulations. In this sense, at the end of 2019, a law on the Start-up Act relates to the creation of a specific support and governance framework for startups under Senegalese law, the establishment of a legal regime adapted to the registration and labelling of Senegalese startups, the creation of a resource center dedicated to Senegalese startups, in particular to facilitate labelling procedures as well as the effectiveness of the support mechanisms put in place. It also offers a set of relevant incentives that align with the imperative of promoting and supporting the development of the Senegalese startup.

At the sectoral level, there are clear advances in the telecommunications and digital innovation sector. The Orange Sonatel group recently inaugurated the Orange Digital Center in Dakar. This third place of innovation supports entrepreneurs, from training to technical support to investment. Fablabs in the heart of Dakar were recently opened (DefkoAkniep). The Senegal Digital Strategy 2016–2025 (SN2025) aims to accelerate the deployment of IT infrastructure, beyond the current level of service quality and cost competitiveness. The country is committed to building a digital technology park in Diamniadio (45 min from central Dakar) and developing a business-friendly tax policy to catalyse foreign investment in the sector. Thus, Senegal is the main supplier of IT services and the leading provider in the outsourcing of business processes in French-speaking sub-Saharan Africa (Ministry of Commerce, Senegal, 2018 ).

Finally, at the regional level, within the framework of WAEMU and the African Industrial Property Organization, the Senegalese Agency for Industrial Property and Technological Innovation (called ASPIT) supervises and supports innovative projects while subsidizing them when projects are promising.

In total, we can sum up the efforts relating to S&T policy as follows (Table 5 ).

Culture and demand of learning

We have grouped these two variables because they are difficult to assess from secondary data. Learning culture refers to in-company training, which is particularly difficult to quantify in an economy where informality is notorious. This variable therefore requires a more in-depth field study in a given sector or territory.

On the demand for learning, two points should be noted: the nature of the labour markets and the number of research professors. The labour markets are saturated and the professional integration of young doctors in Senegal is a real obstacle course, due to poor management of institutions and lack of supervision and lack of financial means (Doucouré, 2014 ).

The demand for qualified personnel in the public sector (public and private higher education) can be assessed through the national recruitment of research professors. However, data on R&D in the private sector are not available and remain only appreciable in the agricultural sector, which is representative of overall R&D. Because many Senegalese companies face limited competition, nothing prevents them from investing in R&D. But most do not have a long-term view of the potential benefits of research, and many find it unnecessary to invest because new technologies will come to them from the public sector or from abroad. As their R&D resources are modest in terms of infrastructure, only a few maintain research staff and, if necessary, the available staff is very low.

According to the Higher Ministry of Higher Education, Research and Innovation ( 2019 ), the staff of research professors is 1757 men and 302 women (2017 statistics) in the public sector and 250 permanent male teachers in the private sector and 85 women. According to the Higher Ministry of Higher Education, Research and Innovation ( 2019 ), the staff of research professors is 1757 men and 302 women (2017 statistics) in the public sector and 250 permanent male teachers in the private sector and 85 women. These data mark the insufficiency of research teaching staff, in comparison with other African economies such as Cameroon, which certainly does not have the same population and student density, but which exceeds 4400 research professors in the public.

Learning links

In a context of public policy reform to build national innovation systems, stakeholder action is being challenged. It can be analysed by focusing on collaborations between institutions dedicated to training, learning capacities and undertakings without claiming to deal with the exhaustiveness of the interactions that it would be necessary to analyse.

“Horizontal collaborations” (actors with the same function between firms) often take on an informal aspect in developing economies. Tacit (uncodified) knowledge is transmitted or formed within learning processes and non-market domestic social institutions. The information systems adapted to the needs of the entrepreneurial sector on the resources proposed by national research in terms of new knowledge, results and training capacity have yet to be built.

The “vertical collaborations” between companies and training institutions focus on the conditions for the mobilization of knowledge are codified. They are transmitted in institutionalized learning in universities, research centres or any other service activities. These learning are at the centre of technological absorption mechanisms that mobilize globalized technologies and knowledge.

These vertical collaborations are weakened by several dysfunctions revealed by the works available mainly on the weakness of the courses of technological engineering in academic courses very academic and the lack of finalization of research orientations or training offers in the light of the entrepreneurial demands. A major difficulty is to be able to respond to the need for transformation of technological accompaniment within the informal sector. Faced with the difficulty of public structures to accompany learning processes, skills training carried out by the informal sector, NGOs and private companies via business counselling increase their services in this direction. Their flexibility of intervention makes it possible to better respond to the specificity of local demands. Nevertheless, the creation of coherence in their intervention with the ongoing renewal of public action in higher education is solicited by numerous studies (Fofiri et al.,  2015 ).

In Senegal, not only are relations between enterprises and administrations complex and ambiguous, but there is a wide opposition between the logics of companies, research institutes and business support institutions (Carre, 2002 ). More generally, the absence of an adequate research ecosystem does not allow researchers to flourish. It is at the origin of the qualitative and quantitative weakness of research work, the flight of trained talents and the weak situation in which African researchers currently find themselves in cooperation and collaboration with their partners in developed countries (AUF, 2019 ).

Local readaptation of knowledge

Real Efforts in Indirect Innovation Policies

Extensive efforts have been made by the Senegalese government. These efforts do not concern policies for technological innovation through R&D (apart from the promises made by the government to exceed 1% of Gross Domestic Product), but more indirectly through learning policies or the promotion of key sectors such as digital or entrepreneurship. We also note the participation of several ministries (Commerce/Education/Economy) to deal with these issues.

On higher education, the Emerging Senegal Plan, for example, integrated the desire to develop higher education by supporting the objective of making Dakar an integrated benchmark campus with the creation of at least five schools of international fame. The objective is to strengthen the supply of specialized higher education centred on key sectors of the economic emergence of Senegal and the sub-region and to promote poles of excellence (French Embassy in Senegal, 2019 ). On the promotion of entrepreneurship, the creation of incubators to encourage Information and Communication Technologies (ICT), or ADEPME which sets up a shared-cost fund intended to partially finance non-financial services, including active small- and medium-sized enterprises in ICT, show here too the will of the state to remain leader in its region in the digital sector. While these aspects are very encouraging, it is nevertheless important to respond to the rapid massification of higher education and the problem of financing innovation, which is still difficult (in particular by the presence of 97% of informal structures) (Ministry of Commerce, Senegal, 2018 ). In addition, as the country suffers from a weakness in technology transmission through foreign direct investment and from fragile and unstructured links between actors in the innovation process, it remains important to continue reforming learning institutions and clarifying the architecture of the Senegalese innovation system, too crumbled and scattered.

Inclusive innovations

The Implications in Terms of Economic Development Remain Low but Promising

Policies and regulations can create obstacles and restrictions that sometimes pose a hindrance to innovation (Patanakul & Pinto, 2014 ). In the context of Senegal, it is the macroeconomic conditions that are not favourable to innovation and therefore to growth and economic development. The unemployment rate, the economic dependence of the country, the very significant clientelism, the political context linked to the questioning of democratic principles (following the arrest of an opponent in power) are not favourable to a context of learning and skills creation. Non-formal learning is problematic and remains the dominant form of mastering new technologies (Oyelaran-Oyeyinka & Lal, 2006 ). In addition, the contribution to R&D is low and not representative of Senegalese growth. We must therefore both modernize knowledge while orienting priorities not towards R&D but towards promising sectors.

Inclusion must therefore be directed towards promising sectors while continuing to develop higher education to train qualified employees and reduce the brain drain.

Among the promising sectors previously mentioned: digital or entrepreneurship. And in this sense, the inclusion of Senegal through the digital economy has been a priority set in the national strategic development framework, the “ESP”. The Senegal Digital 2025 strategy also aims to accelerate the deployment of IT infrastructure, which has already reached a high level both in terms of service quality and cost competitiveness. In addition, the country is committed to building a digital technology park and developing a business-friendly tax policy to catalyse foreign investment in the sector. More locally, the Orange Digital Center, which enriches an integrated Senegalese digital ecosystem where public and private actors help, make the country a regional digital hub.

It is therefore not the small contribution to R&D that has a positive effect on economic development, but the various sectoral impulses and learning policies. The importance in this country is therefore given to indirect innovation policies.

The assessment of works on NIS in low- and middle-income countries provides us with two main conclusions:

The first is methodological. If these NIS do not improve, we should first ask the question “who and how were these defined originally?” First, they should be interpreted in a broad sense and therefore defined according to what they really represent and not what they should manage to achieve according to experts or international organisations (hence the question of the relevance of quantitative indicators of S&T), but mainly they should no longer exist as a purpose, but as a way of improving the living conditions of the population concerned. Hence, the many structural errors largely mentioned in the literature could be transformed into real questions on the opportunities/conditions to create knowledge. In the case of Senegal, sectoral, local and national initiatives are commendable and investment in ICTs makes it possible to create knowledge at the level of the population, to democratize new technologies, just as entrepreneurship can improve living conditions of women.

The second is theoretical. The theories of learning are no longer to be proven in this approach. However, it is what they integrate within them that needs to be better defined, better circumscribed. For this, it is a question of better understanding the heterogeneity of the NIS of low-income and middle-income countries through the diversity and richness of their learning techniques (Johnson and Lundvall., 2003 ). While there is large international data on R&D, patents, licenses, or formal levels of education, it is more difficult to understand how systems in low- and middle-income countries learn, beyond the usual techniques of education. And to grasp it, we must analyse the amount of energy spent by the actors in solving problems, but also the knowledge that the actors have in mastering new knowledge. It is about efforts and trajectories of use of local knowledge by the capacity to (be able to) internalize foreign knowledge. The domestication of knowledge, rehabilitation and local reappropriation are at the heart of the challenges of the NIS of these economies.

In addition, we can make several recommendations in terms of public innovation policies in the case of Senegal:

Encourage innovation ‘in the broad sense’ by continuing to promote promising sectors on which the country is strategically oriented (such as new technologies: fablabs, ecosystems, incubators) without seeking to reproduce models imported from industrialized countries.

Further democratize higher education, and, beyond higher education, learning policies in the broad sense (lifelong learning policies, early learning structures). The country is on an excellent way in terms of apprenticeship reforms, but must still focus on education, as specified in goal 4 of the Sustainable Development Goals set by the UN in 2015.

If R&D is only a small contributor to economic development, as in most African countries, the lessons to be learned can only be directed towards the establishment of bottom-up, local, sectoral policies which seek, among other things, to give meaning to the informal without attempting to formalize it, but rather by seeking to know where skills are created in order to enhance them. Economic development can only improve when political governments will orient their innovation policies on the real expectations and needs of the population and not on the basis of recommendations from R&D experts from imported innovation policies.

https://worldpopulationreview.com/country-rankings/unemployment-by-country

Albuquerque, E., Wilson, S., Glenda, K., & Keun, L. (2015).  Developing national systems of innovation: university-industry interactions in the global south . Cheltenham (UK) & Ottawa: Edward Elgar Publishing & IDRC.

Aguirre-Bastos, C., & Weber, M. (2017). Foresight for shaping national innovation systems in developing countries. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 128 , 186–196.

Article   Google Scholar  

Arcelus, F. J., & Nasierowsky, W. (1999). Interrelationships among the elements of national innovation systems: A statistical evaluation. European Journal of Operational Research, 119 , 235–253.

Arocena, R., & Sutz, J. (1999). Looking at national systems of innovation from the South. Industry and Innovation, 7 (1), 55–75.

Arocena, R., & Sutz, J., (2003).  Understanding underdevelopment today: news perspectives on NSI. GLOBAL Network for Economic of Learning. Innovation and Competence Building Systems, Brazil.

AUF. (2019). Agence Universitaire de la Francophonie, Guide pour l’organisation de la recherche scientifique en Afrique de l’Ouest Francophone, AUF.

Balzat, H. (2002). The theoretical basis and the empirical treatment of National Innovation Systems, Volkswirtschaftliche Diskussionsreihe, Beitrag 232 . WP Universitad Augburg.

Google Scholar  

Bellon, B., & Niosi, J. (1994). Des systèmes nationaux d’innovation ouverts. Revue française d’économie, 9 (1), 79–130.

Bertelsen, P., & Muller, J. (2003). Changing the outlook: explicating the indigenous system of innovation in Tanzania. In M. Muchie, P. Gammeltoft, & B. A. Lundvall (Eds.), Putting Africa First: the making of African Innovation Systems (pp. 123–141). Aalborg University Press, Denmark.

Binz, C., & Truffer, B. (2017). Global innovation systems – a conceptual framework for innovation dynamics in transnational contexts. Research Policy, 46 , 1284–1298.

Carre, H. (2002). Innovation et développement dans une économie de rente: le cas du secteur agro-alimentaire au Sénégal. In A. Djeflat & B. Boidin (Eds.),  Ajustement et technologie en Afrique (pp.168–187). Série Maghtech, Ed. Publisud.

Casadella, V. (2010). Le système national d’innovation dans les PED, Editions Universitaires Européennes.

Casadella, V., Liu, Z., & Uzunidis, D. (2015).  Innovation capabilities and economic development in open economies . New York: ISTE Ltd, Wiley and Sons.

Chaminade, C., Lundvall, B. A., & Haneef, S. (2018).  Advanced introduction to national innovation systems . Elgar Publishing.

Chang, Y. C., & Chen, M. H. (2004). Comparing approaches to systems of innovation: the knowledge perspective. Technology and Society, 20 , 1–21.

Cooke, P. (2001). Regional innovation systems, clusters and knowledge economy. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10 , 945–974.

Dahmen, E. (1989). Development blocks in industrial economics. In B. Carlsson (Ed.),  Industrials dynamics, technological organizational and structural changes in industries and firms (pp. 109–122). Londres: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

Davies, A., & Hobday, M. (2005). Managing innovation in complex products and systems . Cambridge University Press.

Diallo, M. L. (2004). Le Sénégal, un lion économique ? Essai sur la compétitivité d’un pays du Sahel . Editions Karthala.

Dieng, A. A. (2000). Le Sénégal à la veille du 3eMillénaire in Le Sénégal à la veille du 3e Millénaire, l’Harmattan. Paris, p. 4–19.

Doucouré, B. (2014). L’insertion professionnelle des jeunes docteurs au Sénégal.  Hommes & migrations , 1307 , 87–92.

Ducatel, K. (1988). Learning and skills in the knowledge economy. DRUID Discussion Paper Series. Danemark.

Dugué, P., Michel, I., Kettela, V., & Simon, S. (2018). Diversity of innovation processes in the Niayes market gardening system (Senegal): between conventional intensification and agro-ecological transition. In L. Temple, & E. Comparé Sawadogo (Eds.), Innovation processes in agro-ecological transitions in developing countries  (pp. 117–140). Londres: ISTE-Wiley.

Edquist, C. (1997). Systems of innovation, technologies, institutions and organizations . Pinter.

Edquist, C. (2001). The system of innovation approach and innovation policy: an account of the state of the art, DRUID Conference. Aalborg School. Danemark.

Emerging Senegal Plan. (2018). Disponible sur. https://www.un-page.org/files/public/plan_senegal_emergent.pdf . Accessed May 2020.

Enjolras, M., Camargo, M., & Boly, V. (2018). L’indice d’innovation potentielle(IIP) : un diagnostic de la capacité à innover au service des PME. Revue Internationale P.M.E., 31 (2), 17–25. https://doi.org/10.7202/1049960ar

Esperand, W. N., & Sauder, M. (2012). The dynamism of indicators. In K. E. Davis, B. Kingsbury, & S. E. Merry (Eds.), Indicators as a Technology of Global Governance.   Law and Society Review, 46 (1), 86–109.

Filippetti, A., & Archibugi, D. (2011). Innovation in times of crisis: National systems of innovation, structure and demand. Research Policy, 40 , 179–192.

Fofiri Nzossie, E. J., Temple, L., & Ndjouenkeu, R. (2015). La contribution de la recherche universitaire à la formation d’un système sectoriel d’innovation agro-alimentaire au Cameroun. Innovations, 2 (47), 55–77.  https://www.cairn.info/revue-innovations-2015-2-page-55.htm . Accessed May 2020.

Franceschini, S., Faria, L., & Jurowetzki, R. (2016). Unveiling scientific communities about sustainability and innovation. A bibliometric journey around sustainable terms. Journal of Cleaner Production, 127 , 72–83.

Freeman, C. (1987). Technology policy and economics performances: Lessons from Japan . Pinter.

French Embassy in Senegal. (2017). Fiche Sénégal, Disponible sur. https://www.diplomatie.gouv.fr/IMG/pdf/2019_05_fiche_curie_senegal_cle09a954.pdf . Accessed May 2020.

Furman, J. L, Porter, M., & Stern, S. (2002). The determinants of national innovative capacity. Research Policy, 31 , 899–933.

Gaillard, J., & Bouabib, H. (2017). Le système national de recherche et d'innovation (SNRI) marocain et son internationalisation. In J. Gaillard, & H. Bouabib (Ed.), La recherche scientifique au Maroc et son internationalisation . Sarrebruck.

Godinho, M., Mendoça, S. F., & Pereira, T. S. (2003). Mapping Innovation systems : a framework based on innovation data and indicator. First Globelics conference Rio, Brésil.

Heeks, R., Foster, C., & Nugroho, Y. (2014). New models of inclusive innovation for development. Innovation and Development, 4 (2), 175–185.

Jauhiainen, J. S., & Hooli, L. (2017). Indigenous knowledge and developing countries’ innovation systems: The case of Namibia. International Journal of Innovation Studies, 1 (1), 89–106.

Johnson, B. (1992). Institutional learning. In B. Lundvall (Ed.), National innovation system, toward a theory of innovation and interactive learning (pp. 23–44). Londres: Pinter Publishers.

Johnson, B., Edquist, C., & Lundvall, B. A. (2003). Economic development and the national innovation system approach, First Globelics Conference. Rio. Brésil.

Johnson, B., Lema, R., & Villumsen, G. (2017). Research on innovation and development in the Anthropocene. Globelics Working Paper Series , 2017–01.

Johnson, B., & Lundvall, B. (2003). National system of innovation and economic development. In M. Muchie, P. Gammeltoft, & B. A. Lundvall (Eds.), Putting Africa First: the making of African Innovation Systems (pp. 13–29). Danemark: Aalborg University Press.

Kloeppinger-Todd, R., & Sharma, M. (2010). Innovations in rural and agriculture finance. In R. Kloeppinger-Todd, & M. Sharma (Eds.), Innovations in rural and agriculture finance . International Food Policy Research Institute, 18 (1), 2–5.

IMF Report. (2016). Disponible sur. https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/ar/2016/eng/pdf/ar16_eng.pdf . Accessed May 2020.

Lall, S. (1992). Technological capabilities and industrialization. World Development, 20 (2), 165–186.

Lall, S., & Pietrobelli, C. (2002). Falling to compete . Technology development and technology systems in Africa. Elgar.

Book   Google Scholar  

Lemarchand, G. A. (2010). National science, technology, and innovation systems in Latin America and the Caribbean. Science, Policy studies and documents in LAC, 1 , 15–139. Montevideo: Unesco.

Liu, X., & White, S. (2001). Comparing innovation systems: A framework and application to China’s transitional context. Research Policy, 30 (6), 1091–1114.

Lizuka, M., & Hollanders, H. (2017). The need to customize innovation indicators in developing countries. Working Paper Series 2017–032, UNU-MERIT.

Lundvall, B. A. (1992). National innovation system, toward a theory of innovation and interactive learning . Pinter Publishers.

Lundvall, B. A., & Christensen, J. L. (1999). Extending and deepening the analysis of innovation systems- with empirical illustrations from the DISCO project, DRUID Working Paper N 99–12. Aalborg University. Danemark.

Lundvall, B. A., Johnson, B., Andersen, E. S., & Dalum, B. (2002). National systems of production, innovation and competence building. Research Policy, 31 (2), 213–231.

Lundvall, B. A., & Lema, R. (2014). Growth and structural change in Africa: Development strategies for the learning economy. African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development, 6 (5), 455–466.

Ministry of Commerce, Senegal. (2018). Stratégie d’exportation pour le secteur des technologies de l’information et de l’externalisation des processus métiers du Sénégal 2019–2023 . République du Sénégal.

Ministry of Higher Education, Research and Innovation. (2019). Données statistiques du sous-secteur de l’enseignement supérieur de la recherche et de l’innovation, mars 2019.

Muchie, M., Gammerltoft, P., & Lundvall, B. A. (2003). Putting Africa first: The making of African Innovation Systems . Aalborg University Press.

Naclerio, A. (2004). La dimension systémique du Système National d’Innovation: Une application au cas de l’Argentine (p. 13). Université Paris.

Nelson, R. R. (1993). National innovation systems: A comparative analysis . Oxford University Press.

Nfila, R., & Jain, P. (2011). Managing indigenous knowledge systems in Botswana using information and communication technologies, Proceedings of 1st International Annual Conference of the Faculty of Communication and Information Science. National University of Science & Technology (NUST), Islamabad, Pakistan.

Oyelaran-Oyeyinka, B. (2004). Learning and local knowledge institutions in African industry, Discussion Paper series, UNU/INTECH, Maastricht. Allemagne.

Oyelaran-Oyeyinka, B., & Lal, K. (2006). Learning new technologies by small and medium enterprises in developing countries. Technovation, 2006 , 220–231.

PAQUET Report. (2013). Programme d’amélioration de la qualité, de l’équité et de la transparence. Ministère de l’éducation nationale du Sénégal.

Patanakul, P., & Pinto, J. K. (2014). Examining the roles of government policy on innovation. The Journal of High Technology Management Research, 25 (2), 97–107.

Phils, J. A., Deiglmeier, K., & Miller, D. T. (2008). Rediscovering social innovation. Standford Social Innovation Review, 6 (4), 34–43.

Rao-Nicholson, R., Vorley, T., & Khan, Z. (2017). Social innovation in emerging economies: a national systems of innovation approach.  Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 121 , 228–237.

Schoser, S. (1999). The institutions defining national systems of innovation: a new taxonomy to analyse the impact of globalization, Conférence Annuelle EAEP Economy. Prague.

Segura-Bonilla, O. (2003). Competitiveness, systems of innovation and the learning economy: The forest sector in Costa Rica. Forest Policy and Economics, 5 , 73–384.

Sen, A. (2000). Development as freedom . New York: Anchor Books.

Témé, B. (2016). Financement de l’équipement des producteurs et des intrants. Point de vue des banques et de la microfinance, 40.

Tigabu, A. D., Berkhout, F., & Van Beukering, P. (2015). Technology innovation systems and technology diffusion: Adoption of bio-digestion in an emerging innovation system in Rwanda. Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 90 , 318–330.

Tijssen, R., & Hollanders, H. (2006). Using science and technology indicators to support knowledge based economies. United Nations University Policy Brief 11. UNU‐MERIT

Traore, A., Bocoum, I., & Tamini, L. (2020). 2020, Services financiers : Quelles perspectives pour le déploiement d’innovations agricoles en Afrique ? Économie Rurale, 371 (1), 77–94.

UNESCO. (2015). Report on Science.  https://www.unesco.org/reports/science/2021/fr . Accessed May 2020.

Viotti, E. (2002). National learning systems. A New Approach on Technological Change in Late Industrializing Economies and Evidences from the Cases of Brazil and South Korea, Technological Forecasting and Social Change, 69 (7), 653–680.

Von Hippel, E. (1988). The sources of innovations . Oxford University Press.

Watkins, A., Papaioannou, T., Mugwawa, J., & Kale, D. (2015). National innovation systems and the intermediary role of industry associations in building institutional capacities for innovation in developing countries: a critical review of the literature. Research Policy , 1407–1418.

WIPO. (2019). Global Innovation Index 2019.  https://www.wipo.int/edocs/pubdocs/en/wipo_pub_gii_2019.pdf . Accessed May 2020.

World Bank. (2018). Database. https://microdata.worldbank.org/index.php/home

Xu, Y. R., & Carlsson, B. (2005). Analyzing the dynamics and functionality of technological systems: a manual,’ paper presented at the DRUID summer conference, Copenhagen, June 27–29, 2005.

Download references

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Research Network On Innovation, LEFMI, University of Picardie Jules Verne, Amiens, France

Vanessa Casadella & Sofiane Tahi

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Vanessa Casadella .

Additional information

Publisher's note.

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Casadella, V., Tahi, S. National Innovation Systems in Low-Income and Middle-Income Countries: Re-evaluation of Indicators and Lessons for a Learning Economy in Senegal. J Knowl Econ 14 , 2107–2137 (2023). https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-022-00945-8

Download citation

Received : 02 October 2020

Accepted : 14 January 2022

Published : 24 February 2022

Issue Date : September 2023

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/s13132-022-00945-8

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Find a journal
  • Publish with us
  • Track your research

Feinson, Stephen. 2003. National Innovation Systems Overview and Country Cases . Vol. 1, Sec. 1, Knowledge Flows and Knowledge Collectives: Understanding the Role of Science and Technology Policies in Development. Center for Science, Policy and Outcomes, Columbia University.

Academia.edu no longer supports Internet Explorer.

To browse Academia.edu and the wider internet faster and more securely, please take a few seconds to  upgrade your browser .

Enter the email address you signed up with and we'll email you a reset link.

  • We're Hiring!
  • Help Center

National System of Innovation and Economic Development: A Case Study from China

Profile image of Higor Freitas

2023, Estudo & Debate

Loading Preview

Sorry, preview is currently unavailable. You can download the paper by clicking the button above.

RELATED TOPICS

  •   We're Hiring!
  •   Help Center
  • Find new research papers in:
  • Health Sciences
  • Earth Sciences
  • Cognitive Science
  • Mathematics
  • Computer Science
  • Academia ©2024

A Systems View Across Time and Space

  • Open access
  • Published: 03 June 2016

Entrepreneurship in an open national innovation system (ONIS): a proposal for Mexico

  • Leonel Corona-Treviño 1  

Journal of Innovation and Entrepreneurship volume  5 , Article number:  22 ( 2016 ) Cite this article

5377 Accesses

6 Citations

1 Altmetric

Metrics details

In the context of globalization, international processes do affect the national innovation system (NIS), increasing the relationship between its agents and its components within and with external agents.

The paper seeks to determine the openness and internationalization processes in the internal features of Mexico’s NIS and estimate its impacts. This information could allow for a better use of scientific, technological, and innovation—internal and external—capabilities.

The point of departure is the concept of innovation, which was developed for the industrial revolution where products and technological processes are emphasized, with a scope of radical to incremental innovation, as a function of the level of their impacts. Implicitly, innovation has been conceptualized internally within the company, i.e., closed innovation, especially in large companies with research and development departments. However, companies have undertaken various forms of collaboration to reduce costs particularly for R&D, which fall within the concept of open innovation.

Based on the concept of open innovation, an open national innovation system (ONIS) has been proposed with internal and external components and relationships.

This paper argues that the openness of innovation needs to be applied both at firm level and through a NIS as a way of handling the risks involved in innovation better. Thus, firms’ open innovation must correspond to an ONIS, matching the openness and internationalization of its knowledge components and agents: firms and universities supported through government policies. The empirical analysis is exploratory, based on a direct and indirect source to assess how highly developed the Mexican ONIS is in order to propose some policies.

At macro level, the openness and the international processes do affect the national innovation system (NIS Footnote 1 ) by increasing the relationship and collaboration of its agents and components with external agents. One aspect to be measured is determining the impact of the openness and internationalization (OpIn) processes in the (national) internal features of Mexico’s NIS, through assessing them within the context of the system’s components to facilitate better use of scientific, technological, innovation, and entrepreneurial capabilities, both internal and external, considering that both processes are interrelated in different ways and aspects in each component.

Generalizing to a larger context of Schumpeter’s concept of innovation (Schumpeter 1934 ), with the concept of open innovation Footnote 2 and of internationalization processes, an open national innovation system (ONIS) has been proposed with internal and external components and agents and relationships. The components of the ONIS are the businesses and the entrepreneurs, universities, research centers, technology transfer agents, financing-venture capital and “angels” funding, information systems, intellectual property mechanisms, and diverse government participation and regulation.

Opening up innovation and the NIS are motivated by a desire to increase sources of profits and to diminish the risks of capital investments.

An entrepreneur could overcome some capital risks by widening the scope of their relationships. This means modifying the concept of innovation, which was developed for the industrial revolution—where innovation has been conceptualized as occurring within the company, i.e., “closed innovation.” So companies, especially those with research and development departments, have undertaken various forms of collaboration to reduce costs, particularly for R&D, which fall within the concept of “open innovation,” thus diminishing their vulnerability.

Universities and research centers can also open knowledge application relationships, linking their lines of research with potential users, participating in international consortia and research networks.

Financing is an international activity, which can be open depending on the risks involved in the innovation phases, which is particularly critical at birth (start-up) when the firm starts marketing a product, the novelty of which is often based on the intensive use of scientific and technological knowledge.

Government policies and incentives could be oriented towards developing innovation capabilities regardless of the internal or external resources. In this context, the Mexican diaspora could be a result of public policies, mainly for qualified people.

Literature review

National system of innovation.

The NIS creates and disseminates productive knowledge through interrelated institutions. However, the concept departs from the national space as an attempt to understand the variety of national systems. The tendency has been for it to be applied to closed systems, focusing on a country’s specific conditions. Footnote 3 Therefore, we should return to the open approach, to be based on aspects and external processes that are conducive to or allow seizing opportunities, preventing obstacles and threats in the generation of knowledge and innovation capabilities, both internally and externally. This implies that the NIS’s components besides its internal relations are complemented, or sometimes dominated, by external economic relations and modes of cooperation.

The evolution of the NIS approach can be observed by the inclusion of two aspects: first, the addition of the analysis of services (Howells & Teller 2004 ), and particularly of service innovations, characterized in subsequent phases: assimilation, demarcation, and synthesis (Coombs & Miles 2000 ) (Miles 2008 ), based on a combination of new and old theories and concepts (Djellal & Gallouj 2013 ), and second, the grouping of goods and services (Omachonu & Einspruch 2014 ) in a trajectory of interrelationships between the institutions with its context, evolving as an ecosystem of innovation (Jackson 2011 ).

  • Open innovation

Open innovation is “the use of purposive inflows and outflows of knowledge to accelerate internal innovation, and expand the markets for external use of innovation, respectively” (Chesbrough et al. 2006 ). In general, innovation occurs in a context of waves of “creative destruction” that restructure the whole market in favor of companies that adopt the faster occurring discontinuities. However, the capitalist is usually depicted as the one who manages existing structures, while the relevant issue is how companies are created and destroyed (Schumpeter 1934 ).

Open innovation is a concept which refers to the way to manage the uncertainty involved in the creation of new businesses, especially in the early stages, in order to increase opportunities for benefits or cost reduction (or both) in different phases of the knowledge process. So, risk-laden activities of innovation could have the advantages of “(i) benefits from early involvement in new technologies or business opportunities; (ii) delayed financial commitment; (iii) early exits reducing the downward losses; and (iv) delayed exit in case it spins off a venture” (Vanhaverbeke et al. 2008 ; p. 251).

There is no publication in the literature which considers the OpIn processes of NIS. However, there are some implicit considerations such as the idea that the national system of production should not be considered as a closed system (Etzkowitz & Leydesdorff 2000 ) or that “the specific degree and form of openness determines the dynamics of each national system of production” (Lundvall 1988 ).

The dynamics driving the open innovation sources are internationalization processes, collaboration and alliances with other firms (Hertog 2000 ), advantages based on the potentiality of research, and business models of cooperation (based on (Gassmann et al. 2010 ); p. 4):

Globalization and international division of labor: internationalization of R&D; internationalization of entrepreneurship and migration of talent; outsourcing R&D and alliances; and segmentation of production chains and value

Relations with suppliers and users: integration of supplier and customer participation in the innovation process

Leveraging multiplication of research skills and intellectual assets (patents) with collaborative strategies, including new markets

Institutional and cultural framework: cooperative model innovation instead of a temporary monopoly profit-based model

  • Entrepreneurship

Entrepreneurship is a concept developed to explain the actors of a new wave of firms generating a “creative destruction,” as the diffusion of new combinations of resources renders old industries obsolete. The creation of new and better ways of doing business destroys the established ways (Schumpeter 1934 ).

Entrepreneurship initiatives resulting from technology transfers have a lower probability of surviving (Valls and otros 2012 ), as they face a large uncertainty (Reis 2011 ). This vulnerability can be differentiated according to the business lifecycle—birth, growth, decline, and death—and threats, which vary according to competition (e.g., entry barriers, access to finance, and market rates). In this context, the beginning of the commercialization of a new product, considering the high costs and risks, is called “the valley of death.” Risk also depends on the enterprise’s stage of development, whether it is in incubation or whether it is already marketing new technologies or products. Indeed, companies that operate and develop new technologies and/or are intensive in the use of knowledge, but especially those that generate innovations, show higher death rates. Added to these difficulties inherent in its business is the innovative when putting products (goods and services) onto the market, or developing new processes (Drejer 2004 ). The expectations of higher profits from successful ventures must offset the risks involved.

Entrepreneurship is the ability to bring about change (active) and the ability to absorb changes caused by external factors (passive).

The role of the entrepreneur is that of an individual or individuals who carry out the function of combining the factors required to innovate and who may lose this characteristic when, after a period of time, they merely run the business (Schumpeter 1934 ; p. 88).

Therefore, an entrepreneur is someone who takes a risk, focusing on innovation and improvement that creates upheaval and change. Therefore, the entrepreneur is a disruptor leading to long-run evolutionary growth (Schumpeter 1934 ). This approach which understands small firms as breakthrough innovators is complemented by large firms who undertake more incremental innovation, playing both critical and complementary roles (Baumol 2002 ).

However, there are other points of view: entrepreneurship as matching supply and demand by identifying unnoticed profit opportunities. The entrepreneur is a risk taker by offering new solutions in the market in the face of uncertainty about whether their solutions will be profitable. Finally, the entrepreneur could be seen as a resource shifter managing within firms’ shift resources from lower to higher productivity activities (OECD 2010 ; p. 3).

Universities and research centers

The entrepreneurial university plays a role in NIS as an “umbrella of the self-steering, self-reliant and progressive university,” taking risks, strengthened steering core; expanding developmental periphery; diversifying funding base; stimulating academic heartland; and overall integrating the entrepreneurial culture (Burton 2001 ).

The evolution of the entrepreneurial universities is linked to the interrelations of universities and research centers with firms and the government, as part of the “triple helix model” (Etzkowitz & Leydesdorff 2000 ). The evolution begins with a model of expectation of continuing use and transformation of knowledge in a linear model process (Godin 2006 ). The second phase “entails a laissez-faire policy, nowadays also advocated as shock therapy to reduce the role of the state in Triple Helix I”; and in the third phase, the institutional spheres are overlapping, “with each taking the role of the other and with hybrid organizations emerging at the interfaces” (Etzkowitz & Leydesdorff 2000 ).

The context of changes that impact the universities could be summarized in the following tendencies (Davies 2001 ):

“reductions in public financial support which create an imperative for new and diversified financial sources

continuing pressure on universities from governments and the industrial sector to develop applied research and make available education in forms of delivery congenial to companies and public sector organizations

the lifelong learning movement

globalization of higher education in its various forms and

the opportunities offered by the information/knowledge society revolution.”

The triple helix is extended to other agents, Footnote 4 then a fourth agent “society” is added, which is related in different ways to the triple helix. Footnote 5 These interrelations could be coupled to the framework of “mode 1” of knowledge production to basic university research in a disciplinary structure which evaluate to a “mode 2” which focuses on knowledge application and a knowledge-based problem-solving and interdisciplinary (Etzkowitz & Leydesdorff 2000 ) (Gibbons et al. 1994 ).

The role of governments is oriented towards the regulation, incentives, and promotion and towards public-private partnerships. It has a special function in the internationalization and openness of the economy and the components of the NIS. There is little research on the aspects of governmental policy that help enterprises by facilitating and stimulating the use of a firm’s external capabilities and orienting its impacts on the OpIn (De Jong 2008 ).

It is argued that a better solution to managing the risks of innovation is to apply openness in innovations not only at firm level (Chesbrough 2003 ) but also at the national level with an ONIS framework involving the main agents: firms, universities and research centers, and government.

The working hypothesis is that an ONIS is a better framework which generates entrepreneurship in a society that uses both traditional knowledge and new scientific and technological advances.

From this perspective, globalization processes are levers that increase internal capabilities and opportunities for entrepreneurial activities related to science, technology, and innovation.

The proposal of an ONIS involves several key aspects:

Industrial selection based on the intensity of R&D, high technology, and knowledge intensity and innovativeness

Support for SMEs either a technology-based firm (TBF) or knowledge-intensive business services (KIBS Footnote 6 )

Interactive learning and testing processes between suppliers and clients for innovation

Fostering collaboration and strategic alliances between companies for innovation and diffusion

Exploring outward-looking relationships: in venture capital, technology transfer, partnerships with organizations and companies, international mobility, risk sharing, information networks, and patents

Opportunities from internal and external traditional knowledge to “blending” with the new technologies Footnote 7

An analysis of how enterprises are helped to participate in OpIn through government policies in order to commercialize the knowledge originated through R&D, science, and education and in the market (competition, labor market) and in the firms’ dynamics (entrepreneurship, interactions) is applied to Mexico (Graf & Brau 2013 ).

The Mexican economic system is polarized making it a dual economy with a few big international companies and modern firms on the one hand and many small businesses on the other (op cit. 309). The Mexican NIS is influenced by international agreements, especially NAFTA.

The public innovation incentive is oriented to support firms’ R&D as well as interaction to facilitate the diffusion of scientific knowledge in private and public enterprises. However, the incentives are oriented more towards publishing articles than working in collaboration with enterprises as the public funding system is based on journal citations (op cit. p308). In addition, the firms with a certain degree of innovation can profit from an OpIn.

To measure the innovativeness within the firm’s ambit, an Indico index is applied. The index varies between 0 and 10 points summing up two main components: capabilities for innovation and results (output). The first component consists of knowledge capabilities (hardware, information); employee training (certification, studies degrees); R&D organization and R&D in % of sales; and the relationship with knowledge sources. The second are the outputs: innovations, intellectual propriety and markets and product certifications, and service knowledge intensity (Corona-Treviño 2015 ).

The Indico index is calculated to measure the 42 firms’ innovativeness based on the responses of the chief firm’s R&D and/or executives, who reported up to five more important innovations made in either product, process, organization, or marketing during the last 3 years ( Appendix ).

The results are twofold, first, the assessment of the openness of the Mexico NIS including its main components and, second, some exploration on the firms’ openness.

Mexico’s ONIS has components and relationships with strengths and weaknesses (Fig.  1 ):

In relative terms, Mexico has a good training capacity producing qualified personnel based on research center and university teaching and research activities and networking with its international pairs.

Mexico’s knowledge capacity is good in science, is low in technology, and is poor in indigenous technology transfer and patents.

Patenting by Mexicans is limited (3 % in 2013). Footnote 8 To foster it, policies are needed.

(a) To create a positive environment for registering patents and exploiting them and (b) to anticipate the second patenting generation as commercial products besides the present protection and defense mechanisms (Chien 2010 )

Venture capital and angels for start-ups are scarce, so international sponsorship could contribute a lot if they are willing to consider partnerships with local angels and share the investment risk.

Data firms need to be encouraged to handle niches in information growth, in particular big data.

Government policies are more oriented to developing capabilities (human resources and researchers) than to drive the innovation dynamics. Besides that, the level of resources on R&D is low (0.5 % GDP) compared with other OCDE countries.

Mexico’s qualified “diaspora” is a strategic complement of the ONIS, considering that some of them are entrepreneurs, patenting and carrying out technology transfers, and participating in international knowledge networking. Students funded by Conacyt, many of whom form part of the Mexican diaspora, have developed technology (6.9 %), have been granted patents (3.9 %), have been entrepreneurs (6.14 %), and report that they have been participating in innovations (12.5 %). This means that in this sector of the diaspora, there are people who could potentially contribute to Mexico’s capabilities in these fields.

Open innovation system: ONIS. Source: author’s design

Start-ups, spin-offs

As mentioned in the methodology, an Indico index—which is composed of capacity indicators and results—is applied to measure the innovativeness of the firms. The Indico index for all the 41 firms shows a range from 6.78 down to 1.47 with an average of 4.77, highlighting a group of 21 firms with above average rating. In the top 10 Indico index (more than 5.7 points), nine are KIBS and one is a TBF, so that innovativeness slants towards service firms (Table  1 ).

Considering an efficiency index—calculated by the relation between output over capacity—the first rank varies from 1.22 (Prosa) down to 0.19 (ANB). The average tendency is 1.37 points of innovativeness by one unit of efficiency (though it is not statistical accepted).

The firms show a pattern of external participation involving other agents in their innovations. On one hand, half of the TBF, (3 out of 6 TBFs) and one third of the KIBS (12 out of 35) do their innovations internally. On the other hand, firms’ innovations developed with external participation are (1) working in partnership suppliers (5 KIBS and 1 TBF); (2) clients’ participation (9 KIBS); and (3) collaborating two external agents either outsourcing suppliers or clients (7 KIBS). “Innovation chains” is with three external agents joining forces with the firm (1 KIBS—SIEO, 1 TBF—Mahaua) and is subcontracting the whole innovation, which is without internal participation (1 KIBS—“Comparte Vida,” 1 TBF—Biocris). The 56 % of the firms have either sales, intellectual property, linkages, or certificates, with international relationships which most of them (61 %) have an innovativeness index above the average (Table  2 ).

The current crossroads in Mexico of growing qualified unemployment, as a result of a stagnant economy that generates few jobs, could be partially reversed by productive policies and incentives and also by facilitating the channeling of funds to promote, among other things, technological and knowledge-intensive entrepreneurship services. Both the open innovation of TBFs and KIBS in a framework of ONIS could facilitate policies that allow a better use of the knowledge flows concatenated with the internationalization of entrepreneurship and enterprises in general. One possible source of change could come from the Mexican diaspora. Of 100 Conacyt scholars who stayed abroad, 6 have been entrepreneurs, or involved in technology development; 4 have been granted patents; and 12 have participated in innovations. These capabilities could be very useful in an ONIS.

Conclusions

Mexico lags behind other countries with a higher or similar level of scientific and technological (S&T) development. This is due to the difference between, on the one hand, the relatively significant S&T capacities developed in the country’s higher education institutions and public research centers and, on the other hand, a rather low level of dynamism in the creation of knowledge-based start-ups.

In this context, openness in the ONIS components is proposed, in particular those related with the application and use of knowledge in production, that is, in firms and start-ups, both TBFs and KIBSs: technology development, technology transfer, intellectual property, and financing through venture capital and angels funds.

However, for this to occur, active policies will be necessary on the part of government, research centers, universities, and firms.

An exploratory study of 41 start-ups, based on an Indico index, suggests that KIBS are more innovative (4.8 vs 4.4, respectively) and more efficient (0.72 vs 0.57, respectively) than TBFs.

On one hand, openness with respect to innovation is observed in two thirds of the 35 KIBS and in half of the TBF; the rest handle innovation internally. Ten percent of firms have an innovation chain that is innovating with the participation of clients, suppliers, and subcontractors. On the other hand, the firms’ internationalization is positively related to its innovativeness.

To sum up, the OpIn of innovation needs to be applied both at firm level and through an open NIS as a way of increasing firms’ innovativeness and creating a positive environment through which to manage the risks involved in innovation.

There are now four definitions of innovation systems commonly used in the literature: national, regional, sectorial, and technological. “There are not many studies of the degree of internationalization of innovation systems. The few studies that exist show that National Innovation Systems are becoming internationalized; even if the institutions that support them remain country-specific” (Carlsson 2006 ).

Open innovation has been defined as “… the use of purposive inflows and outflows of knowledge to accelerate internal innovation, and expand the markets for external use of innovation…” (Chesbrough 2003 ).

The concept is proposed by C Freeman when analyzing innovations in Japan. “At the international level two contrasting experiences made a very powerful impression in the 1980s both on policy-makers and on researchers: on the one hand the extraordinary success of first Japan and then South Korea in technological and economic catch-up” (p. 10; Freeman 1995 ).

“The Triple Helix indicator can be extended algorithmically, for example, with local-global as a fourth dimension or, more generally, to an N-tuple of helices” (Leydesdorff 2012 ).

“The ‘Quadruple Helix’ model, through which government, academia, industry, and civil society are seen as key actors promoting a democratic approach to innovation through which strategy development and decision-making are exposed to feedback from key stakeholders, resulting in socially accountable policies and practices” (Carayannis, E.G. & Campbell 2012 ).

“It is critical to consider how these innovation variables interact with one another in the context of goods and services” (Omachonu & Einspruch 2014 ).

This leads to an inclusive alternative, which underlines development based on open knowledge “make room for people to co-produce the knowledge associated with the innovations effectively in society; this implies unorthodox ways of thinking, and a lot of innovation in the design of policies” (Dutrénit & Sutz 2014 ).

In 2013, 302 patents were granted to Mexicans, that is, 3 % of the total (10,343 patents) (IMPI, 2013).

Baumol, W, 2002. The free-market innovation machine: analyzing the growth miracle of capitalism. s.l.: Princenton N.J. USA: Princeton University Press,.

Burton, C. (2001). The entrepreneurial university: new foundations for collegiality, autonomy, and achievement. Higher Education Management, 13 (2), 9–24.

Google Scholar  

Carayannis, EG & Campbell, DF. (2012). Mode 3 knowledge production in quadruple helix innovation systems, s.l. . Springer: SpringerBriefs in Business, 7.

Carlsson, B. (2006). Internationalization of innovation systems: a survey of the literature. Research Policy, 35 , 56–67.

Article   Google Scholar  

Chesbrough, HW. (2003). The era of Open Innovation. MITSloan Management Review .

Chesbrough, H, Vanhaverbeke, W, & West, J. (2006). Open innovation: researching a new paradigm . Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Chien, CV. (2010). From arms race to the marketplace: the complex patent ecosystem and its implications for the patent system. Hastings Law Journal, 62 (2), 297–356.

Coombs, R, & Miles, I. (2000). Measurement and services: the new problematique. En: innovation systems in the service sectors. Measurement and case study analysis (pp. 85–104). Boston-Dordrecht-London: Kluwer.

Corona-Treviño, L. (2015). Índice INDICO: Innovación e las empresas . Mexico: Cepcyt DEPFE UNAM.

Davies, JL. (2001). The emergence of entrepreneurial cultures in European universities. Higher Education Management, 13 (2), 25–44.

De Jong, JWVTK. &. HC. 2008. Policies for open innovation: theory, framework and cases, Helsinki, Finland: research project funded by VISION Era-Net.

Djellal, F, & Gallouj, F. (2013). The productivity challenge in services: measurement and strategic perspectives. The Service Industries Journal, 33 (3-4), 282–299.

Drejer, I. (2004). Identifying innovation in surveys of services: a Schumpeterian perspective. Research Policy, 33 , 551–562.

Dutrénit, G, & Sutz, J. (2014). Introduction. En: National System of Innovation, Social Inclusion and Development: the Latin American experience . Cheltenham UK: Edward Elgar Publishing.

Etzkowitz, H, & Leydesdorff, L. (2000). The dynamics of innovation: from national systems and “mode2” to a triple helix of university-industry-government relations. Research Policy, 29 , 109–123.

Freeman, C. (1995). The ‘National System of Innovation’ in historical perspective. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 19 , 5–24.

Gassmann, O, Enkel, E, & Chesbrough, H. (2010). The future of open innovation. R&D Management, 40 (3), 213–221.

Gibbons, et al. (1994). The new production of knowledge: the dynamics of science and research in contemporary societies . London: Sage.

Godin, B. (2006). The linear model of innovation. The historical construction of an analytical framework. Science, Technology & Human Values, 31 (6), 639–667.

Graf, P, & Braun, A. (2013). A policy perspective on open innovation—the Mexican case. International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Innovation Management, 17 (4/5/6), 296–313.

Hertog, P. (2000). Knowledge-intensive business services as co-producers of innovation. International Journal of Innovation Management, 4 (4), 491–528.

Howells, J, & Teller, B. (2004). Innovation in services: issues at stake and trends . Manchester: University of Manchester.

Jackson, DJJ. (2011). What is an innovation ecosystem? Arlington: National Science Foundation.

Leydesdorff, L. (2012). The triple helix, quadruple helix, …, and an n-tuple of helices: explanatory models for analyzing the knowledge-based economy? Journal of the Knowledge Economy, 3 (1), 25–35.

Lundvall, B-A. (1988). Innovation as an interactive process. In G. Dosi, C. Freeman, R. Nelson, G. Silverberg, & L. Soete (Eds.), Technical change and economic theory (pp. 349–369). London: Pinter.

Miles, I. (2008). Patterns of innovation in service industries. IBM Systems Journal, 47 (1), 115–128.

OECD. (2010). SMEs, entrepreneurship and innovation . Paris: OECD.

Book   Google Scholar  

Omachonu, VK, & Einspruch, NG. (2014). Innovation: implications for goods and services. International Journal of Innovation and Technology Management, 7 (2), 109–127.

Reis, E. (2011). The lean startup. How today’s entrepreneurs use continuous innovation to create radically successful businesses . New York: Crown Business.

Schumpeter, JA. 1934. The theory of economic development: an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle. s.l.: Transaction Publishers.

Valls, J & otros, Y. (2012). Causas de fracaso de los emprendedores . La Coruña: Netbiblo, S. L., Oleiros Coleccion de Estudios Red Emprendia.

Vanhaverbeke, W, Van de Vrande, V, & Chesbrough, H. (2008). Understanding the advantages of open innovation practices in corporate venturing in terms of real options. Creativity and Innovation Management, 17 (4), 251–258.

Download references

Acknowledgements

I will like to thanks the DGAPA-UNAM office for the support to the research project (Papiit IN306115) and the Conacyt`s initiative on the research project "Highly skilled migration", coordinated by Dr Raúl Delgado. The seminars organized through them help to developed the concept of Open National of Innovation System: ONIS. Also thanks to the CEPCyT-FE-UNAM students' paricipation on collecting and analysing the data: Blanca Borja, Aura Melèndez, Araceli Jurado, Dioselina Obispo and Alejandra Miranda.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

Universidad Nacional Autonoma de Mexico, Mexico City, Mexico

Leonel Corona-Treviño

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Leonel Corona-Treviño .

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License ( http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ ), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article.

Corona-Treviño, L. Entrepreneurship in an open national innovation system (ONIS): a proposal for Mexico. J Innov Entrep 5 , 22 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1186/s13731-016-0049-5

Download citation

Received : 19 December 2015

Accepted : 06 May 2016

Published : 03 June 2016

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1186/s13731-016-0049-5

Share this article

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • National innovation system
  • Internationalization

national system of innovation case study

Blog The Education Hub

https://educationhub.blog.gov.uk/2024/08/20/gcse-results-day-2024-number-grading-system/

GCSE results day 2024: Everything you need to know including the number grading system

national system of innovation case study

Thousands of students across the country will soon be finding out their GCSE results and thinking about the next steps in their education.   

Here we explain everything you need to know about the big day, from when results day is, to the current 9-1 grading scale, to what your options are if your results aren’t what you’re expecting.  

When is GCSE results day 2024?  

GCSE results day will be taking place on Thursday the 22 August.     

The results will be made available to schools on Wednesday and available to pick up from your school by 8am on Thursday morning.  

Schools will issue their own instructions on how and when to collect your results.   

When did we change to a number grading scale?  

The shift to the numerical grading system was introduced in England in 2017 firstly in English language, English literature, and maths.  

By 2020 all subjects were shifted to number grades. This means anyone with GCSE results from 2017-2020 will have a combination of both letters and numbers.  

The numerical grading system was to signal more challenging GCSEs and to better differentiate between students’ abilities - particularly at higher grades between the A *-C grades. There only used to be 4 grades between A* and C, now with the numerical grading scale there are 6.  

What do the number grades mean?  

The grades are ranked from 1, the lowest, to 9, the highest.  

The grades don’t exactly translate, but the two grading scales meet at three points as illustrated below.  

The image is a comparison chart from the UK Department for Education, showing the new GCSE grades (9 to 1) alongside the old grades (A* to G). Grade 9 aligns with A*, grades 8 and 7 with A, and so on, down to U, which remains unchanged. The "Results 2024" logo is in the bottom-right corner, with colourful stripes at the top and bottom.

The bottom of grade 7 is aligned with the bottom of grade A, while the bottom of grade 4 is aligned to the bottom of grade C.    

Meanwhile, the bottom of grade 1 is aligned to the bottom of grade G.  

What to do if your results weren’t what you were expecting?  

If your results weren’t what you were expecting, firstly don’t panic. You have options.  

First things first, speak to your school or college – they could be flexible on entry requirements if you’ve just missed your grades.   

They’ll also be able to give you the best tailored advice on whether re-sitting while studying for your next qualifications is a possibility.   

If you’re really unhappy with your results you can enter to resit all GCSE subjects in summer 2025. You can also take autumn exams in GCSE English language and maths.  

Speak to your sixth form or college to decide when it’s the best time for you to resit a GCSE exam.  

Look for other courses with different grade requirements     

Entry requirements vary depending on the college and course. Ask your school for advice, and call your college or another one in your area to see if there’s a space on a course you’re interested in.    

Consider an apprenticeship    

Apprenticeships combine a practical training job with study too. They’re open to you if you’re 16 or over, living in England, and not in full time education.  

As an apprentice you’ll be a paid employee, have the opportunity to work alongside experienced staff, gain job-specific skills, and get time set aside for training and study related to your role.   

You can find out more about how to apply here .  

Talk to a National Careers Service (NCS) adviser    

The National Career Service is a free resource that can help you with your career planning. Give them a call to discuss potential routes into higher education, further education, or the workplace.   

Whatever your results, if you want to find out more about all your education and training options, as well as get practical advice about your exam results, visit the  National Careers Service page  and Skills for Careers to explore your study and work choices.   

You may also be interested in:

  • Results day 2024: What's next after picking up your A level, T level and VTQ results?
  • When is results day 2024? GCSEs, A levels, T Levels and VTQs

Tags: GCSE grade equivalent , gcse number grades , GCSE results , gcse results day 2024 , gsce grades old and new , new gcse grades

Sharing and comments

Share this page, related content and links, about the education hub.

The Education Hub is a site for parents, pupils, education professionals and the media that captures all you need to know about the education system. You’ll find accessible, straightforward information on popular topics, Q&As, interviews, case studies, and more.

Please note that for media enquiries, journalists should call our central Newsdesk on 020 7783 8300. This media-only line operates from Monday to Friday, 8am to 7pm. Outside of these hours the number will divert to the duty media officer.

Members of the public should call our general enquiries line on 0370 000 2288.

Sign up and manage updates

Follow us on social media, search by date.

August 2024
M T W T F S S
 1234
5 7891011
131415161718
2122232425
262728293031  

Comments and moderation policy

Global Report on Food Crises (GRFC) 2024

GRFC 2024

Published by the Food Security Information Network (FSIN) in support of the Global Network against Food Crises (GNAFC), the GRFC 2024 is the reference document for global, regional and country-level acute food insecurity in 2023. The report is the result of a collaborative effort among 16 partners to achieve a consensus-based assessment of acute food insecurity and malnutrition in countries with food crises and aims to inform humanitarian and development action.  

FSIN and Global Network Against Food Crises. 2024. GRFC 2024 . Rome.

When citing this report online please use this link:

https://www.fsinplatform.org/report/global-report-food-crises-2024/

Document File
Global Report on Food Crises 2023 - mid-year update
Global Report on Food Crises 2023
Global Report on Food Crises 2022
Global Report on Food Crises 2021 - September update
Global Report on Food Crises 2021
Global Report on Food Crises 2021 (In brief)
Global Report on Food Crises 2020 - September update In times of COVID-19
Global Report on Food Crises 2020
Global Report on Food Crises 2019 - September update
Global Report on Food Crises 2019
Global Report on Food Crises 2019 (In brief)
Global Report on Food Crises 2019 (Key Messages)
Global Report on Food Crises 2019 (Key Messages) - French
Global Report on Food Crises 2019 (Key Messages) - Arabic

Advanced search

  • About Overview
  • Family of Companies
  • Lochner Cares
  • Markets Overview
  • Bridges & Structures
  • Highways & Roads
  • Transit & Rail
  • Water & Wastewater
  • Services Overview
  • Alternative Delivery
  • Construction Engineering & Inspection
  • Engineering & Design
  • Environmental
  • Program & Construction Management
  • Public Works
  • Careers Overview
  • Open Positions
  • What We Offer

Awards & Recognitions

national system of innovation case study

Lochner Celebrates the Expansion of the SunRunner Bus Rapid Transit System

Last week we celebrated the groundbreaking event for the expansion of the SunRunner Bus Rapid Transit (BRT) system! This important project, led by the Pinellas Suncoast Transit Authority (PSTA), will further enhance connectivity and transit options in St. Pete, Florida.

We are also proud to share that the first phase of the SunRunner has earned the 2024 APTA Excellence in Inclusive Collaboration Award. This national award recognizes the successful partnership between PSTA and its private sector partners: Jones Worley, an African American woman-owned Disadvantaged Business Enterprise (DBE), and Lochner, the prime engineer for the project. Together, we delivered a standout transit solution through thoughtful design and implementation.

This award highlights our commitment to creating an exceptional and inclusive passenger experience. We are excited to continue our work on the SunRunner BRT system and contribute to the future of public transportation in our community.

Click here to learn more about Lochner’s Transit & Rail Practice.

national system of innovation case study

Lochner Celebrates National Aviation Week

This week is National Aviation Week! We’re proud to celebrate our dedicated aviation team across Lochner and our family of […]

Lochner Leads Wildlife Crossing Study for Kentucky Transportation Cabinet

Lochner is leading a wildlife crossing pilot study for the Kentucky Transportation Cabinet (KYTC) that focuses on US 60 and […]

Patricia Christie Joins Lochner’s Tampa Traffic Operations Design Group

We are excited to announce that Patricia Christie, PE, has joined Lochner’s Tampa Traffic Operations Design Group as Traffic Engineering […]

This website uses cookies. Click Accept.

Reference our Privacy Policy for more information on data we collect.

COMMENTS

  1. PDF National Innovation Systems Overview and Country Cases

    The national system of innovation is constituted by the institutions and economic structures affecting the rate and direction of technological change in the society" (Edquist and Lundvall, 1993) A national system of innovation is the system of interacting private and public firms (either large or

  2. 7 Systems of Innovation: Perspectives and Challenges

    The expression "national system of innovation" (NSI) was, in published form, ... , which employ different approaches to the study of NSIs. Nelson emphasizes empirical case studies more heavily than theory development 4 and some of the studies focus narrowly on nations' R&D systems. By contrast, Lundvall ...

  3. Exploring the impact of open innovation on national systems of

    Wim Vanhaverbeke is professor of strategy and innovation at the University of Hasselt (Belgium). He is also visiting professor at ESADE (Spain) and the Vlerick Leuven Gent Management School. He is published in international journals such as Journal of Management Studies, Organization Science, Organization Studies, Journal of Management Studies, and Journal of Business Venturing.

  4. Assessing the Origins, Evolution and Prospects of National Innovation

    The concept of the national innovation system (NIS; Freeman 1987; Lundvall 1992; Nelson 1993) originated between the end of the 1980s and the middle of the 1990s, when it became a popular topic in debates on European industrial policy.Bengt-Åke Lundvall was the first scholar to use this term, noting that the idea was actually proposed by Friedrich List in his book The National System of ...

  5. National innovation systems and dynamic impact of institutional

    In studies by Bergek et al. (2008) and Hekkert and Negro (2009), the successful development of ecological sustainability infrastructure such as various clean technology infrastructure (e.g., biofuels and solar cell technology) strengthens the innovation system because it establishes trajectories and patterns regarding system functions and ...

  6. National systems of innovation

    The perhaps broadest approach to economic performance at the level of a country is the concept of national systems of innovation. Despite the emergence of a compelling literature identifying the persistence of innovative activities and country specific institutional effects, evidence on the nature of national systems of innovation is still missing and a number of crucial questions and answers ...

  7. National Innovation Systems—Analytical Concept and Development Tool

    Fibigerstræde 4. DK-9220 Aalborg Ø. And. Tsinghua University. 29 November 2004. Abstract. The term national system of innovation has been around for more than 20 years and today it. has become ...

  8. National innovation systems : a comparative analysis

    The U.S. national innovation system / David C. Mowery and Nathan Rosenberg; The Japanese system of innovation : past, present, and future / Hiroyuki Odagiri and Akira Goto ... National systems of innovation supporting technical advance in industry : the case of Argentina / Jorge M. Katz and Nestor A. Bercovich; The innovation system of Israel ...

  9. National Innovation System: The System Approach in Historical

    Abstract. In the late 1980s, a new conceptual framework appeared in the science, technology, and innovation studies: the National Innovation System. The framework suggests that the research system's ultimate goal is innovation, and that the system is part of a larger system composed of sectors such as government, university, and industry and ...

  10. National Innovation Systems in Low-Income and Middle-Income Countries

    This case study focuses on secondary data collected at the start of 2021. This study focuses on the qualitative variables proposed to define a national innovation system. Some variables have less value than others insofar as they must be accompanied by microeconomic studies (especially for the culture of learning).

  11. Government‐led innovation acceleration: Case studies of US federal

    The cases considered here are all located within the United States' innovation system, which is ... It is difficult to make sweeping claims about innovation based on three case studies of government support for innovation for national security or domestic public policy. ... (SI) model have proliferated. Variants of the SI model include national ...

  12. National innovation systems and international knowledge flows: an

    By doing so, the questions what a national system of innovation consists of and what such a system means for firms are explored. The cases studied provide a picture of international-sectoral systems, adding up to a loosely interacting innovation system at the national level.

  13. Critical inquiry on National Innovation System: Does NIS fit with

    This study presents four main study areas that can be done within the broad frame of NIS studies in developing county contexts. The first main study area is linked to national innovation policy studies which are mainly focused on three main stages viz, formulation, implementation, and post-evaluation. Hence, this avenue creates a large range of ...

  14. National System of Innovation and Economic Development: a Case Study

    Higor de Freitas. Abstract: is article aims to elucidate the debate between the National Innovation System (SNI) and its. interaction with economic development, emphasizing the characteristics ...

  15. National Innovation Systems: A case study of South Korea and Brazil

    National Innovation Systems: A case study of South Korea and Brazil Kate Ho and Katharina Luban Thursday, 25 March 2004 Coursework for Economic and Public Policy of Technology MSc Technology Management 1. ... The National Innovation System - An Overview Efficiency and intensity of innovative activity in an economic area does not only depend ...

  16. National Innovation Systems: Why They Are Important, And How They Might

    Abstract. We shall argue that the notion of 'national systems of innovation' is a useful one, since it treats explicitly what was ignored in earlier models of technical change: namely, deliberate 'intangible' investment in technological learning activities that involve a variety of institutions (principally business firms, universities, other education and training institutions, and ...

  17. The 'National System of Innovation' in historical perspective

    3. Some contrasting features of national systems of innovation in the 1970s. and 1980s. As empirical evidence and analysis began to accumulate about industrial R&D innovation, both in Japan and in the United States and Europe, it became evident that the success of innovations, their rate of diffusion and the.

  18. National Innovation Systems Overview and Country Cases

    Library. Feinson, Stephen. 2003. National Innovation Systems Overview and Country Cases. Vol. 1, Sec. 1, Knowledge Flows and Knowledge Collectives: Understanding the Role of Science and Technology Policies in Development. Center for Science, Policy and Outcomes, Columbia University. Download PDF.

  19. National System of Innovation and Economic Development: A Case Study

    ISSN 1983-036X 95 3 CHINA'S NATIONAL INNOVATION SYSTEM 3.1 State programs for the development of science and technology In 1985 China initiated a set of reforms on its national innovation system or national apprenticeship system, approving the Resolution of the Central Committee of the Communist Party of China [CCCPC, 1985].

  20. The state of innovation system research: What happens beneath the

    1. Introduction. The late 1980s saw the emergence of a new and more systemic understanding of innovation and diffusion processes. The resulting "National Innovation System" (NIS) framework 1 (Lundvall, 1992, Nelson, 1993, Freeman, 1987) has attracted significant attention among both researchers and policymakers, resulting in the increased importance of the larger field of Innovation ...

  21. PDF The Role of Innovation Policy in The National Innovation System: the

    The role of innovation policy in the NIS: the case of Estonia 251 al. (2004:430) state that two conditions have to be fulfilled for public sector ... understanding of the structure of the national innovation system. In this study, a new comprehensive innovation system model (see Figure 1) was synthesised on

  22. Entrepreneurship in an open national innovation system (ONIS): a

    In the context of globalization, international processes do affect the national innovation system (NIS), increasing the relationship between its agents and its components within and with external agents.The paper seeks to determine the openness and internationalization processes in the internal features of Mexico's NIS and estimate its impacts. This information could allow for a better use ...

  23. GCSE results day 2024: Everything you need to know including the number

    Thousands of students across the country will soon be finding out their GCSE results and thinking about the next steps in their education.. Here we explain everything you need to know about the big day, from when results day is, to the current 9-1 grading scale, to what your options are if your results aren't what you're expecting.

  24. Global Report on Food Crises (GRFC) 2024

    The Global Report on Food Crises (GRFC) 2024 confirms the enormity of the challenge of achieving the goal of ending hunger by 2030. In 2023, nearly 282 million people or 21.5 percent of the analysed population in 59 countries/territories faced high levels of acute food insecurity requiring urgent food and livelihood assistance. This additional 24 million people since 2022 is explained by ...

  25. Lochner Celebrates the Expansion of the SunRunner Bus Rapid Transit

    Last week we celebrated the groundbreaking event for the expansion of the SunRunner Bus Rapid Transit (BRT) system! This important project, led by the Pinellas Suncoast Transit Authority (PSTA), will further enhance connectivity and transit options in St. Pete, Florida. We are also proud to share that the first phase of the SunRunner has earned […]